Do higher public and private debt levels benefit the wealthy? An empirical analysis of top wealth shares in the UK

Glauco De Vita (Centre for Business in Society, Coventry University, Coventry, UK)
Yun Luo (University of Southampton, Southampton, UK)
K. Sandar Kyaw (Cardiff School of Management, Cardiff Metropolitan University, Cardiff, UK)
Kexing Li (Centre for Business in Society, Coventry University, Coventry, UK)

Journal of Economic Studies

ISSN: 0144-3585

Article publication date: 18 October 2024

132

Abstract

Purpose

Despite the concomitant rise in recent decades in both debt levels (public as well as private) and wealth inequality, empirical evidence on the relationship is absent in existing literature. This is striking especially since recent theoretical contributions point to a link between debt and wealth inequality. We contribute to the debate by investigating empirically whether higher levels of UK public and household debt increase the UK wealth concentration at the top 1 and 10% of the wealth distribution.

Design/methodology/approach

We employ the Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) cointegration approach with UK time series data from 1970 to 2019. For robustness, a further analysis using panel data fixed effects estimation on a cross-country sample that also includes France and the USA is undertaken. We also use bootstrapping to conservatively estimate statistical significance.

Findings

Higher levels of public and household debt are found to increase wealth concentration at the top 1 and 10%. The effect is stronger for household debt. Fixed effects estimation on a cross-country dataset supports the results for the UK.

Originality/value

This study is the first to investigate empirically whether rising levels of UK public and household debt benefit the wealthy and thus widen the gap between the “haves” and “have-nots”.

Keywords

Citation

De Vita, G., Luo, Y., Kyaw, K.S. and Li, K. (2024), "Do higher public and private debt levels benefit the wealthy? An empirical analysis of top wealth shares in the UK", Journal of Economic Studies, Vol. 51 No. 9, pp. 338-357. https://doi.org/10.1108/JES-07-2024-0458

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2024, Glauco De Vita, Yun Luo, K. Sandar Kyaw and Kexing Li

License

Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


1. Introduction

Over the last two decades, two significant phenomena particularly in many high-income, Western economies have drawn special attention: rising levels of debt (public as well as private) and a persistent widening of the uneven distribution of personal wealth. In the UK, these trends have been particularly pronounced, stimulating academic research and attracting much public interest. This article contributes to the literature studying the wealth distribution of the UK by investigating the impact of both public and household debt on the wealth shares of the top 1% and 10% of UK households.

The inequality debate gained momentum with the publication of Piketty’s (2014) Capital in the Twenty-First Century [1], in which he warned that the tendency of returns on capital (Piketty’s “r”, which includes returns on bonds, stocks or any form of property) to exceed the rate of economic growth (Piketty’s “g”) viewed by Piketty as the main driver of wealth concentration at the top – threatens to generate extreme inequalities [2]. Specifically, Piketty alerts to a state of affairs whereby accumulated wealth becomes more concentrated among those whose earnings come from owning capital and assets rather than from labour. Partly due to difficulties related to the measurement of the uneven distribution of personal wealth, several studies published since then have, therefore, focused on the empirical evidence pertaining to the evolution of the top wealth shares (see, inter alia, Kopczuk, 2015; Alvaredo et al., 2018), which has now become the measure of choice to capture wealth inequality (see also Islam and McGillivray, 2020) [3].

Wealth inequality fell throughout much of the 20th century, with the proportion of UK wealth held by the richest 10% falling from more than 90% to around 50% by the 1980s. The concentration of wealth of the top 1% also decreased dramatically, from 70% in 1914 to 16% in 1980 (Alvaredo et al., 2018). However, since 1980, the trend has reversed (Atkinson and Piketty, 2007; Piketty and Saez, 2003).

As shown in Figures 1 and 2, from the mid-1980s and early 1990s, the wealth shares of both the top 1% and 10% have risen considerably. In 2019, the richest 1% of the UK population held more than a fifth of total wealth, while the top decile captured nearly 60%.

Since the 2007/2008 financial crisis, the wealth shares of the richest have been said to have been fuelled by rising asset prices such as housing values, land and stocks rather than saving. Alvaredo et al. (2018, p. 26), too, highlight an increase in top wealth shares since 1980, but argue that the increase “notably” pertains to “the distribution of wealth excluding housing”.

Several factors have been considered as determinants of wealth concentration in relevant literature such as monetary policy (Mumtaz and Theophilopoulou, 2020), house prices (Fuller et al., 2020) and mortality rates (Berman and Morelli, 2021). In this paper, we add to this literature by testing whether rising levels of UK public debt and private (household) debt may have contributed to the higher concentration of wealth at the top of the wealth distribution.

Starting with public sector debt, in March 2021 UK net debt reached 103% of GDP, the highest level since 1960. Figure 3 plots the UK public debt over GDP ratio from 1970 to 2021. From 1970 to 1990 net debt continued to fall drastically from over 70% of GDP to below 30%. This steady reduction was part of a trend primarily due to a prolonged, peace-time period of economic growth. Public sector debt then rose again but after a few years of government financial restraint, from 1995, it fell to 29% of GDP by 2002. Since then, UK’s national debt has recorded a steady rise. Over the period 2002–2007, the rise was mainly due to increased government spending on health and education alongside higher social security spending. The sharp rise from 2008 to 2015 has much to do with the economic recession that followed the financial crisis, including the bailouts of Northern Rock, Royal Bank of Scotland, Lloyds and other banks. After 2015 and up to 2019, the effects of the UK government’s efforts to slow down the rise in public debt by reducing the budget deficit and adopting strict spending limits were dampened by lower-than-expected economic growth. From 2020, net public debt as a proportion of GDP rose sharply due to the impact of the Coronavirus and associated policy measures.

Undoubtedly, the global financial crisis and, more recently, the policy measures adopted by governments worldwide to counter the coronavirus pandemic (COVID-19) impact on their respective economies have led to a severe deterioration of fiscal positions in many countries (further threatened by attempts by some administrations to tackle the cost-of-living crisis via further public sector borrowing). Hence, although 103% of GDP is a very high level of debt by post-war UK standards, it is worth noting that some other developed countries have an even bigger public debt problem. Italy and Japan are a case in point, with a national debt as a proportion of GDP of 154% and 256%, respectively. However, unlike Italy and Japan, the UK also has worryingly high levels of private (household) debt. As shown in Figure 4, UK household debt over GDP has recorded, in between modest and short-lived reductions, a staggering rise over the past 50 years, from around 30% in 1970 to 90% in 2021. Although household debt has been rising in all advanced economies over the same period, in 2021 the ratio of household debt over GDP in Japan and Italy was just over 67% and 45%, respectively. The sharp rise in UK household debt over the 1980s was in large part fuelled by a boom in consumer credit (credit cards and loans), whereas the steep increase over the decade preceding the global financial crisis can be primarily accounted for by increases in mortgage debt.

The general arguments linking debt to wealth inequality are intuitively plausible. For example, when governments borrow, they must honour interest payments to bondholders, which are usually paid out of taxes. The payment of interest on government debt must, therefore, involve a transfer of wealth from taxpayers to bondholders. Since – pension funds notwithstanding – government bonds are held to a great extent by those at the top of the wealth distribution, this tax-and-interest-payment cycle redistributes wealth in favour of the wealthy. Some recent theoretical studies have offered more sophisticated hypotheses on the mechanisms through which public debt and/or household debt may affect wealth concentration (see Maebayashi and Konishi, 2021; Borissov and Kalk, 2020; Mian et al., 2021). However, this literature is not vast, and even less attention has been paid to uncovering the empirics behind the theory. Indeed, empirical evidence of the relationship is almost nonexistent.

Part of the reason for the paucity of applied work on the debt-wealth inequality nexus is the lack of good quality wealth data, over long time periods and/or for enough countries (Fuller et al., 2020). For cross-countries studies, the common approach adopted to circumvent such data constraint has been to use income inequality as a proxy for wealth inequality (see, e.g. Ezrachi et al., 2023). However, wealth is far more concentrated than income (Cagetti and De Nardi, 2008), thus making income inequality a poor proxy. Moreover, because wealth is an accumulated stock rather than an annual flow, its distribution tends to move more slowly than income distribution (Kopczuk, 2015).

Wealth data can be obtained from three sources: administrative data from income and inheritance tax, lists of large wealth holders and household surveys. The distribution of wealth is rarely observed directly in available administrative data. Moreover, the abandonment of wealth and sometimes inheritance taxes in some countries often makes it difficult to track top wealth holders. Rich lists partially address this gap. For example, in the UK, the Sunday Times Rich List (STRL) published by the British newspaper The Sunday Times since 1989. However, the problem with lists such as STRL is that their methodology is often opaque. For instance, STRL measures “identifiable wealth” merely from data available in the public domain, yet it excludes bank accounts and “small” shareholdings in private equity portfolios. It also lacks transparency as to the precise consideration given to liabilities. Additionally, by design, rich lists only concern a tiny fraction of the population, the “super rich”. Household surveys, too, are problematic as they may not capture a fully representative sample of all individuals, and suffer from low response rates, especially from high-wealth individuals (Kopczuk, 2015). In the UK, the Office for National Statistics’ (ONS) Wealth and Assets Survey (WAS) measures the well-being of households and individuals in terms of their assets, savings, debt and planning for retirement. However, WAS has been in existence only since 2006, which coupled with its biennial interview wave pattern, makes it difficult to exploit the data within a time series framework. Furthermore, WAS contains some very wealthy outliers. Finally, as Advani et al. (2021) observe, WAS underestimates total wealth. They find that fitting a Pareto distribution (which, since Klass et al., 2006, is often taken as a good fit for skewed and heavy-tailed distributions such as those of wealth holdings) to UK wealth data, both WAS and STRL “underestimate family wealth at the very top of the distribution” (Advani et al., 2021, p. 399).

In an attempt to overcome the limitations of the wealth data sources discussed above, researchers working on the World Inequality Database (WID) combined different data sources: national accounts, survey data, fiscal data and wealth rankings. The WID database can be regarded as the most reliable in tracking the evolution of wealth levels and, therefore, it is the one we draw from to collect data of the top wealth shares.

We contribute to the wealth inequality literature by examining the impact of both public and household debt on wealth inequality in the context of UK data from 1970 to 2019. Specifically, we investigate the effects of UK public and household debt on the top 1% and 10% wealth shares. We employ the Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) cointegration approach (Pesaran et al., 2001). Our findings indicate that higher debt levels, both public and private, significantly increase the concentration of wealth in the top 1% and 10%. For both wealth shares, the effect is most pronounced for household debt. A further analysis using panel data fixed effects estimation on a cross-country sample that also includes France and the USA broadly attests to the robustness of our results for the UK.

2. Theoretical channels linking debt to wealth inequality

As noted earlier, the effect of public debt on wealth inequality is relatively straightforward under non-distortionary taxation. Michel and Pestieau (1998, 2005) were the first to suggest that although public borrowing is neutral in aggregate terms, it redistributes income from the poorer non-altruists to the richer altruists who own the entire capital stock and public debt. Within this two-agent framework, the rich altruists increase their equilibrium wealth by exactly the amount of increase in public debt while the poor non-altruists maintain their zero wealth. As a result, wealth inequality increases unambiguously.

Departing from a strictly steady-state perspective in which public debt converges, Maebayashi and Konishi (2021) consider how public debt affects wealth inequality in the presence of distortionary taxation, such as an income tax on the rich altruists’ bond holdings. Their results can be summarised as follows. First, when the initial public debt is small, the economy can reach a stable equilibrium in which both public debt and wealth inequality converge to a stable level, but when the initial public debt is very large, the economy with higher wealth inequality can converge to a stable equilibrium whereas the economy with low wealth inequality cannot converge to any stable equilibrium. If the economy is in an unsustainable region, both public debt and wealth inequality continue to increase, and the economy goes bankrupt in the long run. Second, an increase in the public deficit ratio makes the public debt less sustainable, with wealth inequality increasing as public debt grows into an unsustainable region. Third, if the government taxes the bequests of the rich and redistributes them to the poor, the economy is more likely to fall into the region in which the public debt is not sustainable and wealth inequality continues to increase. Finally, in the long run, a rise in the public deficit ratio increases wealth inequality and reduces the growth rate. An increase in the redistributive tax reduces both wealth inequality and the growth rate, and hence, leads to the trade-off between equality and growth. However, it should be noted that in their two-period overlapping generations model, the division of the population into two income classes (“the rich” and “the poor”) cannot be affected by the public debt policy. Instead, it operates on the basis of heterogeneity of agents’ preferences, particularly in discount factors, and on utility deriving from a “joy of giving” savings motive, with the rich old generation bequeathing larger wealth to children than the poor old generation does.

Borissov and Kalk (2020) investigate the role of public debt in the dynamics of wealth inequality by considering an endogenous growth model with positional concerns (where agents’ decisions depend not only on their absolute level of consumption but also on the perception of their social status) and public debt financed by distortionary income taxes. Their framework entails two possible regimes depending on the strength of positional externality: egalitarian and two-class. In the egalitarian regime, the wealth distribution gravitates toward full equality regardless of the initial state. In the two-class regime (the rich and the poor), the entire stock of capital and public debt is eventually owned by the dynasties which were the richest in the beginning and all other dynasties become poor. Borissov and Kalk’s (2020) model advances Maebayashi and Konishi (2021) by allowing zero optimal bequests using a less stringent form of altruism and by treating agents as identical except for their initial wealth. They show that if positional concerns are not too strong, there is a threshold level of the debt-to-GDP ratio. Below the tipping point, the economy converges to a unique egalitarian balanced-growth equilibrium, whereas if this ratio is above the threshold level, the economy ends up in a two-class balanced-growth equilibrium with poor dynasties saving nothing in the long run and rich dynasties owning the entire capital stock and public debt. A key result is that the growth rate in the egalitarian equilibrium is higher than that in any possible two-class equilibrium. Hence, a reduction in public debt may cause the economy to switch from the two-class regime to the egalitarian regime and accelerate growth. Crucially, their findings also suggest that government policies aimed at reducing initial inequality using public debt may, in fact, increase wealth inequality in the long run.

Chatzouz (2020) examines the implications of public debt for wealth inequality using a stylized Diamond model where the distinction between dynamically efficient and inefficient economies (i.e. whether real interest rates are greater or lower than real economic growth) is the criterion that defines the burden of taxation. Here too, agents derive utility from bequests, with young agents inheriting income from their parents who are distinguished by their past savings and by their degree of altruism (with richer parents saving a larger fraction of their incomes). His model predicts that public debt distributes wealth unequally. The result is explained by the increase in the after-tax wage inequality driven by the general equilibrium effects of public debt, namely the crowd-out of physical capital. Furthermore, the redistribution of resources across generations augments the effect by raising the bequest motive of the rich.

A distinct yet related contribution to the debate on the implications of high debt levels for wealth inequality comes from Mian et al.’s (2021) theory of indebted demand, according to which high levels of debt lower aggregate demand, and thus the natural rate of interest. Their model introduces non-homothetic consumption-saving behaviour into an otherwise conventional two-agent endowment economy, where the saver saves a larger proportion of lifetime income than the borrower. Since in the model the wealthy lend to the rest of the population, household debt is an important financial asset in the portfolio of the wealthy. This assumption too is plausible, indeed a stylized fact, as shown by Mian et al. (2020) who present evidence that a large part of household debt in the US reflects the top 1% of the wealth distribution lending to the bottom 90%. They find that large debt levels weigh negatively on aggregate demand: as borrowers cut consumption to pay off their debts to savers, the latter, having a higher propensity to save, only partially offset the drop in borrowers’ spending. Mian et al. (2021) label the depressed demand resulting from elevated debt levels as “indebted demand”, greater levels of which are associated with reduced natural interest rates. As Mian et al. (2021, p. 3) summarise, “From the perspective of savers, reduced interest rates are necessary to balance the greater desire to save in response to greater debt service payments”. Their framework predicts a number of patterns found in the data, one of which, given our interest, is that a rise in top-income shares shifts resources from borrowers to savers, pushing down interest rates due to savers’ greater desire to save. Lower interest rates, in turn, stimulate more debt, causing indebted demand – as debt is simply a further shift of resources in the form of debt service payments from borrowers to savers.

Although low in number, the above theoretical contributions should suffice in justifying our hypothesis that high levels of both public debt and household debt may benefit those at the top of the wealth distribution, at the expense of the rest.

As mentioned earlier, due to data availability limitations, applied studies investigating the factors that may drive wealth inequality (as opposed to income inequality) are even fewer, and empirical analyses testing the specific effect of public or household debt on the top wealth shares are inexistent, at both country and cross-country level.

Piketty’s work also sparked interest in investigating the role that housing plays in the dynamics of wealth inequality and, more specifically, how house prices impact wealth-to-income ratios. This strand of literature (Bonnet et al., 2014; Fuller et al., 2020) has focused particular attention on another of Piketty’s observations according to which, a smaller driver of rising wealth-to-income ratios can be attributed to the price effect associated with capital gains. In other words, not only do savers accumulate returns on their ownership of property, but they also benefit from any appreciation of the underlying assets. Some authors, such as Bonnet et al. (2014), have challenged this logic. According to Bonnet et al. (2014), it is rent, not housing prices, that matters for the dynamics of wealth inequality, because rent represents both the actual income of housing capital for landlords and the dwelling costs saved by owner-occupiers. As such, proper measurement of capital requires correcting the value of housing capital by measuring it on actual rental prices and not housing prices. When Bonnet et al. (2014) apply this adjustment, they find that the capital/income ratio is actually stable or only slightly higher in the countries in their sample (France, the US, the UK and Canada) with the sole exception of Germany.

Fuller et al. (2020) too, took up issue with Piketty’s argument. They argued that, unlike financial assets, which are mostly held by those at the top of the wealth distribution, the wealth held via home ownership tends to be more widely distributed among middle-income earners. This would suggest that greater rates of home ownership redirect (housing) wealth towards a more egalitarian distribution. Using the wealth-to-income ratio as a proxy for overall levels of wealth inequality, Fuller et al. (2020) investigate the impact of house prices on wealth inequality in 13 Western European and non-European countries. They find that in both the short and long run, wealth-to-income ratios are driven mostly by housing prices and, to a lesser extent, by price changes in other financial assets.

The absence of empirical studies investigating the impact of public and/or household debt on wealth inequality speaks volumes as to the difficulties in collecting relevant data not only on the distribution of wealth but also on variables that, going by the driving factors highlighted in theoretical models, may drive the observed wealth concentration at the top. The level of inherited wealth or bequests, which has been said to account for most of capital formation (see Cagetti and De Nardi, 2008), is a case in point, with no UK data on the intergenerational transmission of wealth being available for estimation.

3. Empirical framework and data

3.1 Empirical framework

Despite the difficulties with the availability of data discussed above, our empirical specification is as follows:

Eq. (1)WEALTHt=β0+β1GOV_DEBT_GDPt+β2HOU_DEBT_GDPt+β3STOCKt+β4HOUSEPRICEt+β5RENTALt+β6INTRATEt+β7WELFAREt+β8TAXt+β9GINIt+ut
where WEALTH is wealth inequality measured by the 1% and 10% top wealth shares; GOV_DEBT_GDP is the ratio of public debt over GDP; HOU_DEBT_GDP is the ratio of household sector debt to GDP; STOCK is a stock share index; HOUSEPRICE is the UK house price index; RENTAL is a measure of UK rental price inflation; INTRATE denotes long-term (issued at par with 20 years to maturity) bond yields; WELFARE is total welfare spending as a percentage of GDP; TAX refers to natural logarithm of tax revenue; and GINI is a measure of income inequality.

Following Pesaran et al. (2001), we rewrite Eq. (1) as a conditional ARDL model:

Eq. (2)WEALTHt=C0+C1t+Σk=1pβ1WEALTHtk+Σk=0pβ2GOVDEBTGDPtk+Σk=0pβ3HOUDEBTGDPtk+Σk=0pβ4STOCKCAPtk+Σk=0pβ5HOUSEPRICEtk+Σk=0pβ6RENTALtk+φ1Dwealth+φ2Dgov+φ3Dhou+λ1Σk=0pβ7INTRATEtk+Σk=0pβ8WELFAREtk+Σk=0pβ9TAXtk+Σk=0pβ10GINItk+λ1WEALTHt1+λ2GOVDEBTGDPt1+λ3HOUDEBTGDPt1+λ4STOCKCAPt1+λ5HOUSEPRICEt1+λ6RENTALt1λ7INTRATEt1+λ8WELFAREt1+λ9TAXt1+λ10GINIt1+φt
where C0 and C1t are the drift and trend components, and Dwealth, Dgov and Dhou are year dummies to account for structural breaks for WEALTH, GOV_DEBT_GDP and HOU_DEBT_GDP identified from the Zivot-Andrews’ UR test. In Eq. (2), the long-run relationship is determined by the coefficients λs, and the short-run relationship by Σs. Following Pesaran et al. (2001), the null hypothesis of no cointegration (H0:λ1=λ2=λ10=0) is tested using the F-statistic. We also use Banerjee et al. (1998) t-BDM test, with a null hypothesis of no cointegration H0:λ1=0 against H1:λ1<0. The computed test statistics are then compared with two sets of critical values, upper and lower. If the estimated value of the F or t-BDM statistic lies above the upper critical bound, the null is rejected, indicating the existence of a long-run relationship.

One advantage of the ARDL cointegration approach is that it is applicable when it is not known with certainty whether the variables are I(0) or I(1). However, since the method requires that no variable be I(2) or higher, we still test for the order of integration of all the variables. We employ the Phillips and Perron (1988) unit root (UR) test and, to account for a structural break, the Zivot and Andrews (1992) UR test. Although our interest centres on the long-run equilibrium relationship, as originally noted by Pesaran and Shin (1999), another virtue of the ARDL approach lies in the rich set of dynamics of the underlying ARDL specification, which allows the ARDL-based estimator to satisfactorily address potential endogeneity problems [4].

By way of robustness, we then extend the analysis to a cross-country setting by estimating a fixed effects panel data model for the UK, USA and France for the period 1980–2019. Eq. (1) can, therefore, be rewritten as:

Eq. (3)WEALTHit=β0+β1GOV_DEBT_GDPit1+β2HOU_DEBT_GDPit1+β3STOCKit1+β4HOUSEPRICEit1+β5RENTALit1+β6INTRATEit1+β7WELFAREit1+β8TAXit1+β9GINIit1+ut
where the subscript i refers to country i. We estimate Eq. (3) with a fixed effects regression with Driscoll-Kraay standard errors (Driscoll and Kraay, 1998), which are robust to general forms of cross-sectional dependence and general serial correlation across time when the temporal dimension becomes large. To mitigate the potential endogeneity problem, following De Vita and Luo (2021), we lag all independent variables by one year.

3.2 Data

We estimate Eq. (2) using annual UK data over the period 1970–2019. Although WID wealth data stretch even further back, the start date of our sample is dictated by the availability of UK public debt data, which only goes as far back as 1970. The end date (2019) is dictated by the advent of the COVID-19 pandemic, consideration of which would skew the data. Fifty observations may seem a fairly small sample, however, given that cointegration is concerned with the long run, our low frequency ensures that the dataset covers a long period spanning half a century, thus rendering possible an analysis of long-run convergence in the relationship under scrutiny [5].

In terms of control variables, we begin by including variables reflecting the three types of capital investment highlighted in Piketty’s wealth inequality hypothesis, namely stock, government bonds, and real estate. We, therefore, control for the share price index (STOCK), the interest rate on long-term government debt (INTRATE) and the house price index (HOUSEPRICE). The first two variables are expected to increase the concentration of top wealth shares while, given the widespread ownership of property across the wealth distribution, house prices may not necessarily have a positive effect on top holders of wealth. Based on Bonnet et al.’s (2014) arguments, we also include a measure of UK rental price inflation (RENTAL) based on rental price rather than housing price. Furthermore, we control for social welfare spending (WELFARE), which by its redistributive nature may be expected to decrease wealth inequality. We also account for taxation (TAX), specifically revenues from taxes on income and investment profits. The UK has a form of progressive taxation which limits the amount of after-tax income that individuals/households can direct towards capital investment (Piketty and Saez, 2003). Higher tax revenues are likely to reflect higher taxation for richer groups, thereby reducing the potential for wealth accumulation. Finally, we control for income inequality using the Gini index (GINI). Although earnings from labour may not necessarily correlate with the wealth concentrated at the top (on this point, see Benhabib et al., 2017), the Gini index may capture wage effect disparities stemming from the influence of competition policy and enforcement on the competitiveness of labour markets, a variable for which data covering our full sample period is unavailable (e.g. the competition law index by Bradford and Chilton, 2018, ends in 2010).

Table 1 presents descriptive statistics for our time series’ estimation variables. All of the values appear to be reasonable and concord with prior studies’ reports. Over the sample period, the average wealth shares of the top 1% is 19.88% with a standard deviation of 3.07%, and for the top 10% is 54.11% with a standard deviation of 4.77%. On average, the level of household debt-to-GDP ratio (mean = 59.6915) is higher than the level of government debt-to-GDP ratio (mean = 53.4314). Table 2 presents the correlation coefficients of the variables, and their respective statistical significance, showing fairly reassuring values. The definition of each variable, and their respective sources, are detailed in Appendix 1.

4. Results

Table 3 presents the results of the UR tests using Phillips and Perron (1988) in columns (1) and (2), and Zivot and Andrews (1992) in columns (3) to (5). The two UR tests show some discordance. According to the former, all series are I(1) in levels and first-difference stationary while going by the Zivot and Andrews’ test, HOU_DEBT_GDP, STOCK, RENTAL, HOUSEPRICE, WELFARE, TAX and GINI, are already I(0) in levels. We attribute the discrepancy to the fact that the Zivot and Andrews’ test accounts for a structural break in the evolution of the series. However, reassuringly, both tests confirm that none of the variables are I(2) or higher. Hence, we can safely proceed to apply the ARDL bounds testing approach to cointegration.

Table 4 presents the results of the ARDL regressions on the top 1% and 10% wealth shares. For both regressions, the F and t-BDM test statistics exceed the upper critical bounds at customary significance levels. We, therefore, conclude that there is a long-run (cointegration) relationship among the selected variables [6].

Although Table 4 also reports the error correction terms (ECTs) of the short-run equations [7], our central interest lies in the long-run estimates. The estimated long-run coefficient of GOV_DEBT_GDP is positive and statistically significant at the 5% level for both regressions on the top 1% and 10% wealth shares with estimated coefficients of 0.0008 and 0.0011, respectively. Similarly, with estimated coefficients of 0.0018 and 0.0013, HOU_DEBT_GDP is positive and statistically significant (at the 1% level) for both regressions. The results are consistent with the predictions of previous theoretical studies that high levels of public and household debt may increase wealth at the top of the distribution (e.g. Borissov and Kalk, 2020; Mian et al., 2021). With respect to our control variables, the investment return on stocks (STOCK) shows a positive and statistically significant effect (at 1%) on both top wealth shares, a finding consistent with Piketty’s wealth inequality hypothesis. The results also show that more welfare spending (WELFARE) reduces the top 1% and 10% wealth shares, with statistically significant coefficients across the two specifications. On the other hand, higher revenues from taxation (TAX) reduce the top 10% wealth share but not the top 1%. The negative estimated coefficients of TAX and WELFARE might be explained by the fact that: (1) ceteris paribus, people in the bottom wealth share stand to benefit more (and lose less) from increased welfare spending than those in the top wealth share; and (2) higher tax revenues are likely to reflect higher taxes for high-income earners (the rich) but not necessary the wealthiest group (the richest 1%). HOUSEPRICE, RENTAL and INTRATE do not show any effect on top wealth shares at any acceptable statistical level of significance.

Diagnostic tests reassure about the validity of the model. There is no evidence of serial correlation and heteroscedasticity, and normality holds. Additionally, the cumulative sum (CUSUM) tests for structural stability (Figure 5) confirm that the parameters are stable.

5. Robustness

As noted earlier, issues related to data availability and degrees of freedom in particular, impose considerable limitations for estimation within a single-country time series framework. The same constraints apply to conducting robustness tests. Given that increasing levels of both debt and wealth inequality are patterns common to many advanced economies, in order to address this challenge, we test the robustness of our results by extending the analysis to a small cross-country, panel data setting that includes in addition to the UK, the US and France [8].

At the cost of losing early time series data for the years from 1970 to 1979 (social spending data are only available from 1980), the panel data setting allows us to gain relevant cross-sectional data for two other countries, up to 2019, thus raising the number of available observations from 50 to 117. Such cross-country approach also warrants us an opportunity to: (1) assess the sensitivity of our main results to a different estimation method, namely, panel fixed effects, and to alternative, international measures of a selection of variables included in our model [9]; and (2) control for, through the use of dummies, country specific and time invariant effects.

The results of this panel data permutation, presented in Table 5, broadly corroborate the time series results for the UK. Our key variables of interest “public debt” and “household debt” are both statistically significant at the 1% level under both the top 1% and 10% wealth shares specifications. The magnitudes of the respective estimated coefficients are also similar to those of Table 4. Specifically, household debt is found to have a stronger impact on the top 1% and 10% wealth shares than public debt (almost double the effect), with estimated coefficients for HOU_DEBT_GDP recording magnitudes of 0.0010 and 0.0014, respectively.

In terms of control variables, STOCK is confirmed to have a positive and statistically significant effect (at 1%) on both top wealth shares, with estimated coefficients of very similar magnitudes to those of Table 4. Interestingly, under these panel data estimations HOUSEPRICE becomes statistically significant (at 1%), but with negatively signed estimated coefficients of 0.0011 and 0.0010 under the top 1% and top 10% specifications. On the other hand, our house RENTAL price variable, becomes significantly positive under the top 1% wealth share specification, but stays insignificant under the top 10% specification. We rationalise the negative effect of house prices (HOUSEPRICE) on top wealth shares on the basis of the fact that, as noted by Fuller et al. (2020), the value of the (housing) wealth held via home ownership is more widely distributed among middle-income earners. It follows that rising house prices may actually reduce the wealth disparity as measured solely by top shares, as analysed here. This also means that there is no inherent conflict between our results and those by Fuller et al. (2020), whose estimates show a positive coefficient for house prices on regressions taking the “wealth-to-income ratio” as a proxy for overall levels of wealth inequality, which as discussed earlier, heavily underestimates inequality in the upper tail of the wealth distribution (on this point, see also Islam and McGillivray, 2020).

Our results for RENTAL align even more closely to the arguments and evidence put forward by Bonnet et al. (2014), according to whom it is rent, not housing prices, that matter for wealth inequality (at least as far as top wealth shares are concerned). Since according to this logic house rent also represents the actual income of housing capital for owners of large property portfolios, RENTAL can constitute a substantial form of return on capital investments for the very rich. This is consistent with our result of a positive and significant coefficient of very large magnitude (0.2577) for the top 1% wealth share but not for the top 10% of wealth holders, for whom such returns are evidently of lesser significance.

Finally, tax and social spending become statistically insignificant in these panel estimations. These results suggest that existing taxes on income and profits as well as welfare spending targeting the needy via family and children, unemployment and housing benefits as well as social protection measures adopted to combat poverty, do not significantly reduce wealth inequality measured against wealth holders at the top of the wealth distribution.

6. Conclusions

Although at the theoretical level several recent studies have hypothesised a relationship between debt and wealth inequality, empirical evidence on whether public and household debt impact on top wealth shares is lacking. Using UK time series data on the top 1% and 10% wealth shares, we filled this gap by letting the available data speak.

Using an ARDL approach to cointegration on UK data from 1970 to 2019, our results show that higher debt levels, both public and private, increase concentration in the top 1% and 10% wealth shares. For both top wealth shares, the effect is most pronounced in the case of private, household debt. Higher stock value is also found to increase wealth inequality while welfare spending and general taxation have a negative effect.

Fixed effects panel estimation on a small cross-country dataset provides broad support to the time series results for the UK. These robustness estimations confirm that the wealthiest 1% and 10% benefit from increases in both public and household debt levels as well as rises in the value of stock. The panel estimates also suggest that while rising house prices have a mitigating effect on wealth inequality, thereby reducing disparity across the wealth distribution, rising rental housing values substantially increase the wealth captured by the richest 1%. Under these cross-country specifications, the top 1% and 10% wealth shares are not significantly moved by social spending, taxation, and interest rates.

Policy towards inequality in the form of progressive taxes aimed at achieving vertical equity is often criticised for generating both a disincentive effect to greater earnings from labour and moral hazard resulting from redistribution in favour of the welfare state. These criticisms, which apply to taxing income from labour mostly to address poverty, appear to lose relevance in the context of taxing wealth, particularly wealth concentrated at the top of the distribution. These considerations make it all the more striking that wealth, whether acquired through capital gains, inheritance or ownership of land and property, remains relatively under-taxed compared to income from labour or even consumption.

Our findings, by demonstrating the significant role high debt levels play in fuelling the increase in top wealth shares, highlight the importance that policy should play in preventing the accumulation of large public deficits and high levels of household debt as a way to reduce rising wealth inequity. This is consistent with Borissov and Kalk (2020) who suggested that government policies aimed at reducing initial inequality using public debt may, in fact, increase wealth inequality in the long run. Our findings also suggest a potential virtuous cycle in taxing high wealth more effectively (rather than relying solely on general taxation and welfare spending in the fight against inequality) as government revenue raised in this way would reduce the need for higher government borrowing which, in turn, would avoid further debt-induced rises in the wealth concentrated at the top.

Figures

UK top 1% wealth share 1970 to 2019

Figure 1

UK top 1% wealth share 1970 to 2019

UK top 10% wealth share 1970 to 2019

Figure 2

UK top 10% wealth share 1970 to 2019

UK public debt over GDP, 1970 to March 2021

Figure 3

UK public debt over GDP, 1970 to March 2021

UK debt to GDP ratio for household sector

Figure 4

UK debt to GDP ratio for household sector

Cumulative sum (CUSUM) test for top 1% and top 10% wealth shares

Figure 5

Cumulative sum (CUSUM) test for top 1% and top 10% wealth shares

Descriptive statistics

MeanMedianMaxMinStd. Dev
TOP10.19880.19930.28350.15200.0307
TOP100.54110.53810.65990.45590.0477
GOV_DEBT_GDP53.431446.991186.923228.866318.2725
HOU_DEBT-GDP59.691557.875095.800029.200023.1943
STOCK51.916249.2266111.88353.220537.56223
RENTAL0.06950.04890.28980.00460.0593
HOUSEPRICE0.08920.07850.3757−0.08880.0939
INTRATE46.170330.4589120.95152.127638.5010
WELFARE7.61897.966114.76580.93584.1691
TAX7.92286.060016.97004.75004.1147
GINI31.366033.500034.400025.60003.2801

Source(s): Authors’ calculations

Correlation matrix

TOP1TOP10GOV_DEBT_GDPHOU_DEBT-GDPSTOCK
TOP11
TOP100.9621***1
GOV_DEBT_GDP0.5904***0.6316***1
HOU_DEBT-GDP−0.0492−0.11740.3044**1
STOCK0.0008−0.06080.3217**0.9106***1
RENTAL−0.05190.0038−0.2334*−0.7513***−0.7695***
HOUSEPRICE0.21150.2614*−0.1655−0.4515***−0.3761***
INTRATE−0.6497***−0.6718***−0.3782***−0.2096−0.3055**
WELFARE−0.3145**−0.3614***0.12390.9294***0.9199***
TAX−0.3158**−0.4266***−0.06470.8565***0.8583***
HOUSEPRICEINTRATEWELFARETAXGINI
HOUSEPRICE1
INTRATE0.3206**1
WELFARE0.1081−0.01611
TAX−0.6781***−0.4462***−0.10051
GINI−0.7436***−0.4372***−0.01240.9087***1

Note(s): Variables are defined in Appendix 1. All pairwise correlations are calculated using the maximum number of observations available in the sample. *, ** and *** denote statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1% level

Source(s): Authors’ calculations

Unit root tests

VariablesPhillips-Perron test statisticZivot-Andrews test statistic
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
LevelFirst-differenceLevelFirst-differenceT_b
TOP1−2.533−7.122***−4.849 (1)−8.632 (0)***1984
TOP10−2.160−7.620***−4.961 (1)−9.980 (0)**1984
GOV_DEBT_GDP−1.522−2.924***−3.779 (1)−5.119 (0)***2008
HOU_DEBT_GDP−1.852−2.189**−4.125 (2)** 2011
STOCK−0.345−4.447***−5.217 (1)*** 1996
RENTAL−2.712−3.557***−7.494 (1)*** 1983
HOUSEPRICE−1.759−6.492***−6.006 (1)** 1998
INTRATE−2.636−4.978***−2.071 (5)−7.349 (4)***1983
WELFARE−0.052−5.303***−5.507 (1)*** 1982
TAX−0.810−4.006***−3.328 (1)*** 2008
GINI1.384−2.373**−3.346 (2)*** 1985

Note(s): The optimal lag structure of the PP test is chosen based on the Newey–West bandwidth with Bartlett weights and is displayed in parentheses. TB denotes the time of break. The optimal lag structure of the Zivot and Andrews’ (1992) test is chosen based on the Schwarz Information Criterion and is displayed in parentheses. For all PP tests, a constant and a time trend are included for the regressions in levels, but the time trend is removed in the first difference equations. ***, **, * denote the rejection of the null of a unit root at 1, 5 and 10%, respectively

Source(s): Authors’ calculations

Impact of debt on top 1% and top 10% (time series estimation: UK)

Dependent variable:Top 1%Dependent variable:Top 10%
VariablesCoefficientst-statisticsCoefficientst-statistics
Long-run coefficients
GOV_DEBT_GDP0.0008**2.49330.0011**2.3661
HOU_DEBT-GDP0.0018***4.64660.0013***3.1170
STOCK0.0006***2.97210.0010***4.0697
HOUSEPRICE−0.0161−0.48250.03520.9667
RENTAL0.06971.11280.01890.1868
INTRATE−0.0049−1.4172−0.0011−0.3663
WELFARE−0.0027***−4.3084−0.0025***−2.7944
TAX−0.0169−1.0026−0.0655***−3.0464
GINI0.00060.2396−0.0017−0.5705
Error correction terms (ECTs)
Coint. Eq(−1)*−0.9689***−8.1980−0.9346***−9.5571
DiagnosticsF-statisticsp-valueF-statisticsp-value
SC2.47740.10521.14460.3345
HETER0.96480.52811.28670.2671
NORM2.17020.33783.98000.1366
CUSUMYes Yes
Bounds testing for cointegration
F-statistics4.9925*** 6.8935***
t-BMD−6.1118*** −6.9350***
Linearity testt-statisticsp-valuet-statisticsp-value
RESET1.32810.19621.47210.1530

Note(s): At the 1%, 5% and 10% level of significance, the pair of critical values (bound) for the F-statistics and t-BMD are 2.97–4.24 and −3.96 to −5.79, 2.43 to 3.56 and −3.41 to −5.15, 2.16 to 3.24 and −3.13 to −4.82. SC denotes the Breusch and Godfrey serial correlation test, HETER denotes the Breusch and Pagan heteroscedasticity test and NORM denotes the Jarque–Bera test for normality. RESET denotes the Ramsey RESET regression specification error test to test for linearity. In our regressions, we include (though not report) three-year dummy variables to account for the structural breaks identified in the UR tests in Table 3: TOP1 and TOP10 in 1984, GOV_DEBT_GDP in 2008 and HOU_DEBT_GDP in 2011

Source(s): Authors’ calculations

Impact of debt on top 1% and top 10% wealth shares (panel estimation: UK, US and France)

Top 1%Top 10%
GOV_DEBT_GDP0.0005**0.0008***
(0.0002)(0.0001)
HOU_DEBT-GDP0.0010***0.0014***
(0.0003)(0.0002)
STOCK0.0007***0.0006***
(0.0001)(0.0001)
INTRATE−0.00200.0000
(0.0013)(0.0015)
HOUSEPRICE−0.0011***−0.0010***
(0.0003)(0.0002)
RENTAL0.2577***0.0863
(0.0731)(0.1443)
SOCIALSPEND0.0015−0.0016
(0.0010)(0.0010)
TAX0.0008−0.0002
(0.0018)(0.0015)
GINI−0.0013−0.0027
(0.0010)(0.0016)
No. of observations117117
No. of countries33
R20.85520.8422

Note(s): The Hausman test is used in all regressions to inform the choice between fixed- and random-effects specifications, p-value = 0.000 rejects the null hypothesis that the coefficients are the same between fixed and random effects. All independent variables have a lag of one year. Constants are not reported. Driscoll-Kraay standard errors are reported in parentheses. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05 and * p < 0.1 denote statistical significance at the 1, 5 and 10% level, respectively

Source(s): Authors’ calculations

Notes

1.

The reason why inequality has recently made its way to the centre of attention in political debate and academic research has obviously much to do with the new “gilded age” of growing inequality where top wealthholders accumulate wealth at an almost unprecedented scale. But, of course, the debate has been around for centuries among social scientists and historians, concerning itself not only with poverty but with the ethics of an uneven distribution of wealth, a dichotomy eloquently captured in Shakespeare’s King Lear where the nobleman Gloucester, enunciates: “So distribution should undo excess, And each man have enough” (King Lear, Act 4, Scene 1).

2.

For West European nations, the socio-political consequences of further unequal allocation between the “haves” and “have nots” cannot be overstated. To the extent that such inequity is perceived as unfair and illegitimate, extreme wealth inequality could foment social division and civil conflict. It should come as no surprise, therefore, that “reducing inequality” also features as a UN Sustainable Development Goal (UNSDG 10).

3.

The wealth-to-income ratio is a highly imperfect measure of wealth inequality. As Fuller et al. (2020) note, it may alert us to general trends in wealth inequality, but it could only do so contingent upon certain conditions. Moreover, the ratio reflects, at best, the overall level of wealth distribution while contemporaneously underestimating inequality in the upper tail. As Islam and McGillivray (2020, p. 3) highlight, “the top wealth holders may experience faster growth of their wealth, whereas the bottom wealth holders may experience slower or even decrease their wealth growth”.

4.

We, therefore, account for the possibility that there may be feedback or reverse causality effects running from wealth inequality to public debt levels via government policies aimed at reducing initial inequality using public debt (see Borissov and Kalk, 2020).

5.

As Hakkio and Rush (1991, p. 579) note, because “cointegration is a long-run property, […] we often need long spans of data to properly test it”. Similarly, Shiller and Perron (1985) argue that when testing for URs, the length of the time series is far more important than the frequency of observation. Finally, Taylor (1995, p. 112) states that the deficiency of using less than 50 annual observations “should be compensated by the fact that the data set spans nearly half a century”.

6.

Asymptotic critical values for the t and F cointegration tests are in Pesaran et al. (2001). However, it is well known that for these tests p-values using the tabulated values are likely to be oversized (Cushman et al., 2023). Thus, we also used the bootstrapping procedure of McNown et al. (2018) which yields more conservative results than does use of tabulated critical values. We find that even when using bootstrapped critical values a cointegrating relationship is confirmed among the variables at the 1% significance level for the t-BMD test under both the top 1% and 10% wealth share specifications (with bootstrapped critical values of −3.06 and −4.43, respectively) and at the 5% significance level for the F-test (with values of 4.64 and 4.41 for the respective wealth share model specifications).

7.

The ECTs, −0.9689 and −0.9346 for the top 1% and 10% models respectively, are statistically significant, suggesting that it takes just over one year for full adjustment from short-run disequilibrium to long-run equilibrium to be completed.

8.

We were unable to add additional countries since social spending data from 1980 are only available for the UK, France and the US.

9.

In the panel data analysis, due to data availability limitations, we use the ratio of social spending over GDP as a proxy for welfare spending. The long-term interest rate used in the panel analysis is the 10 years long-term bond yields. Additionally, we use the house price index in the panel estimation while the change in the house price index is used in the time series estimations. The definition of each variable and their respective sources are detailed in Appendix 2.

Disclosure statement: The authors report there are no competing interests to declare.

Data availability: Data used in this paper are available from the authors upon request.

Appendix 1

Table A1

Table A1

Variables and sources for time series estimation

VariablesVariable definitionSources
TOP1Share of Top 1% in net personal wealthWorld Inequality Database (WID)
TOP10Share of Top 10% in net personal wealthWID
GOV_DEBT_GDPGeneral government debt over GDP ratioEuropean Commission’s Directorate General for Economic and Financial Affairs (AMECO)
HOU_DEBT-GDPDebt-to-GDP ratio for household sectorBank for International Settlements (BIS)
STOCKA share price index measures how the value of the stocks in the index is changingOECD Macroeconomic
Indicators database
RENTALChange for consumer price indices (CPIs) for actual rentals for housingOECD Main Economic Indicators Database
HOUSEPRICEChange of house price index. House price index captures changes in the value of residential properties and uses sales data collected on residential housing transactions, whether for cash or with a mortgageOffice for National Statistics (ONS)
INTRATELong-term bond yields are issued at par with 20 years to maturityInternational Monetary Fund, retrieved from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
WELFARERatio of welfare spending over GDP; welfare spending includes family and children benefits, unemployment, housing, social exclusion, R&D social protection and social protectionHM Treasury PESA, retrieved from ukpublicspendng.ac.uk
TAXNatural logarithm of tax revenue. Tax revenue is defined as the revenues collected from taxes on income and profits, social security contributions, taxes levied on goods and services, payroll taxes, taxes on the ownership and transfer of property, and other taxesOECD Macroeconomic
Indicators database
GINIMeasure of inequality derived from the Lorenz curveSWIID Version 6.9 (Solt, 2019)

Source(s): Authors' own creation

Appendix 2

Table A2

Table A2

Variables and sources for panel data estimation

VariablesVariable definitionSources
TOP1Share of Top 1% in net personal wealthWorld Inequality Database (WID)
TOP10Share of Top 10% in net personal wealthWID
GOV_DEBT_GDPGeneral government debt over GDP ratioEuropean Commission’s Directorate General for Economic and Financial Affairs (AMECO) and FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
HOU_DEBT-GDPDebt-to-GDP ratio for household sectorBank for International Settlements (BIS)
STOCKA share price index measures how the value of the stocks in the index is changing and refers to how much money investors would make as a result of investing in that basket of sharesOECD Main Economic Indicators database
RENTALConsumer price indices (CPIs) for actual rentals for housingOECD Main Economic Indicators database
HOUSEPRICEThe real house price index is given by the ratio of the nominal house price index to the consumers’ expenditure deflator in each country from the OECD national accounts database. It covers the sales of newly built and existing dwellings, following the recommendations from the Residential Property Prices Indices (RPPI) manualOECD Main Economic Indicators database
INTRATELong-Term bond yields are issued at par with 10 years to maturityOECD Main Economic Indicators database
SOCIALSPENDRatio of social spending over GDP. Social expenditure comprises cash benefits, direct in-kind provision of goods and services, and tax breaks with social purposes. Benefits may be targeted at low-income households, the elderly, disabled, sick, unemployed, or young personsOECD Main Economic Indicators database
TAXRatio of tax revenue over GDP. Tax revenue is defined as the revenues collected from taxes on income and profits, social security contributions, taxes levied on goods and services, payroll taxes, taxes on the ownership and transfer of property, and other taxesOECD Macroeconomic
Indicators database
GINIMeasure of inequality derived from the Lorenz curveSWIID Version 6.9 (Solt, 2019)

Source(s): Authors' own creation

References

Advani, A., Bangham, G. and Leslie, J. (2021), “The UK's wealth distribution and characteristics of high-wealth households”, Fiscal Studies, Vol. 42 Nos 3-4, pp. 397-430, doi: 10.1111/1475-5890.12286.

Alvaredo, F., Atkinson, A.B. and Morelli, S. (2018), “Top wealth shares in the UK over more than a century”, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 162 C, pp. 26-47, doi: 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2018.02.008.

Atkinson, A.B. and Piketty, T. (2007), Top Incomes over the Twentieth Century: A Contrast between Continental European and English-speaking Countries, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Banerjee, A., Dolado, J. and Mestre, R. (1998), “Error-correction mechanism tests for cointegration in a single-equation framework”, Journal of Time Series Analysis, Vol. 19 No. 3, pp. 267-283, doi: 10.1111/1467-9892.00091.

Benhabib, J., Bisin, A. and Luo, M. (2017), “Earnings inequality and other determinants of wealth inequality”, The American Economic Review, Vol. 107 No. 5, pp. 593-597, doi: 10.1257/aer.p20171005.

Berman, Y. and Morelli, S. (2021), “On the distribution of estates and the distribution of wealth: evidence from the dead”, NBER Working Paper, 28546.

Bonnet, O., Bono, P.-H., Chapelle, G. and Wasmer, E. (2014), “Does housing capital contribute to inequality? A comment on Thomas Piketty's capital in the 21st century”, Sciences Po Economics Discussion Papers, Vol. 7, pp. 1-12.

Borissov, K. and Kalk, A. (2020), “Public debt, positional concerns, and wealth inequality”, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, Vol. 170 C, pp. 96-111, doi: 10.1016/j.jebo.2019.11.029.

Bradford, A. and Chilton, A.S. (2018), “Competition law around the world from 1989 to 2010: the competition law index”, Journal of Competition Law and Economics, Vol. 14 No. 3, pp. 393-432, doi: 10.1093/joclec/nhy011.

Cagetti, M. and De Nardi, M. (2008), “Wealth inequality: data and models”, Macroeconomic Dynamics, Vol. 12 No. S2, pp. 285-313, doi: 10.1017/s1365100507070150.

Chatzouz, M. (2020), “Public debt and wealth inequality”, SSRN, available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3531199

Cushman, D.O., De Vita, G. and Trachanas, E. (2023), “Is the Fisher effect asymmetric? Cointegration analysis and expectations measurement”, International Journal of Finance and Economics, Vol. 28 No. 4, pp. 3727-3748, doi: 10.1002/ijfe.2616.

De Vita, G. and Luo, Y. (2021), “Financialization, household debt and income inequality: empirical evidence”, International Journal of Finance and Economics, Vol. 26 No. 2, pp. 1917-1937, doi: 10.1002/ijfe.1886.

Driscoll, J.C. and Kraay, A.C. (1998), “Consistent covariance matrix estimation with spatially dependent panel data”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 80 No. 4, pp. 549-560, doi: 10.1162/003465398557825.

Ezrachi, A., Zac, A. and Decker, C. (2023), “The effects of competition law on inequality - an incidental by-product or a path for societal change?”, Journal of Antitrust Enforcement, Vol. 11 No. 1, pp. 51-73, doi: 10.1093/jaenfo/jnac011.

Fuller, G.W., Johnston, A. and Regan, A. (2020), “Housing prices and wealth inequality in western Europe”, West European Politics, Vol. 43 No. 2, pp. 297-320, doi: 10.1080/01402382.2018.1561054.

Hakkio, C.S. and Rush, M. (1991), “Cointegration: how short is the long run?”, Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 10 No. 4, pp. 571-581, doi: 10.1016/0261-5606(91)90008-8.

Islam, M.R. and McGillivray, M. (2020), “Wealth inequality, governance and economic growth”, Economic Modelling, Vol. 88 C, pp. 1-13, doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2019.06.017.

Klass, O.S., Biham, O., Levy, M., Malcai, O. and Solomon, S. (2006), “The Forbes 400 and the Pareto wealth distribution”, Economics Letters, Vol. 90 No. 2, pp. 290-295, doi: 10.1016/j.econlet.2005.08.020.

Kopczuk, W. (2015), “What do we know about the evolution of top wealth shares in the United States?”, The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 29 No. 1, pp. 47-66, doi: 10.1257/jep.29.1.47.

Maebayashi, N. and Konishi, K. (2021), “Sustainability of public debt and inequality in a general equilibrium model”, Macroeconomic Dynamics, Vol. 25 No. 4, pp. 874-895, doi: 10.1017/s1365100519000336.

McNown, R., Sam, C.Y. and Goh, S.K. (2018), “Bootstrapping the autoregressive distributed lag test for cointegration”, Applied Economics, Vol. 50 No. 13, pp. 1509-1521, doi: 10.1080/00036846.2017.1366643.

Mian, A.R., Straub, L. and Sufi, A. (2020), “The saving glut of the rich”, NBER Working Paper, 26941.

Mian, A., Straub, L. and Sufi, A. (2021), “Indebted demand”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 136 No. 4, pp. 2243-2307, doi: 10.1093/qje/qjab007.

Michel, P. and Pestieau, P. (1998), “Fiscal policy in a growth model with both altruistic and nonaltruistic agents”, Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 64 No. 3, pp. 682-697, doi: 10.2307/1060786.

Michel, P. and Pestieau, P. (2005), “Fiscal policy with agents differing in altruism and ability”, Economica, Vol. 72 No. 285, pp. 121-135, doi: 10.1111/j.0013-0427.2005.00404.x.

Mumtaz, H. and Theophilopoulou, A. (2020), “Monetary policy and wealth inequality over the great recession in the UK. An empirical analysis”, European Economic Review, Vol. 130 C, 103598, doi: 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2020.103598.

Pesaran, M.H. and Shin, Y. (1999), “An autoregressive distributed-lag modelling approach to cointegration analysis”, in Strøm, S. (Ed.), Econometrics and economic theory in the 20th century: The Ragnar Frisch centennial symposium, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 371-413.

Pesaran, M.H., Shin, Y. and Smith, R.J. (2001), “Bounds testing approaches to the analysis of level relationships”, Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol. 16 No. 3, pp. 289-326, doi: 10.1002/jae.616.

Phillips, P.C. and Perron, P. (1988), “Testing for a unit root in time series regression”, Biometrika, Vol. 75 No. 2, pp. 335-346, doi: 10.2307/2336182.

Piketty, T. (2014), Capital in the Twenty-First Century, The Belkanp Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.

Piketty, T. and Saez, E. (2003), “Income inequality in the United States, 1913-1998”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 118 No. 1, pp. 1-39, doi: 10.1162/00335530360535135.

Shiller, R.J. and Perron, P. (1985), “Testing the random walk hypothesis: power versus frequency of observation”, Economics Letters, Vol. 18 No. 4, pp. 381-386, doi: 10.1016/0165-1765(85)90058-8.

Solt, F. (2019), “The standardized world income inequality database, Versions 8-9”, Harvard Dataverse, V7, doi: 10.7910/DVN/LM4OWF.

Taylor, M.P. (1995), “Modeling the demand for U.K. broad money”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 75 No. 1, pp. 112-117, doi: 10.2307/2109632.

Zivot, E. and Andrews, D.W.K. (1992), “Further evidence on the great crash, the oil-price shock, and the unit-root hypothesis”, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, Vol. 10 No. 3, pp. 251-270, doi: 10.1080/07350015.1992.10509904.

Acknowledgements

The authors thank The Leverhulme Trust for funding this research (RPG-2023-099) under their Research Project Grant scheme. We are also grateful to the Editor of this journal, Prof. Mohsen Bahmani-Oskooee, alongside two anonymous referees, for useful comments on an early draft. The principal, first-named author of this paper also wishes to thank the participants at the 28th International Conference on Macroeconomic Analysis and International Finance (Crete, Greece) for helpful feedback.

Corresponding author

Glauco De Vita can be contacted at: ac1377@coventry.ac.uk

Related articles