Abstract
Purpose
This article aims to investigate how institutional characteristics affect the level of financial development of economies collectively and compare between developed and undeveloped economies.
Design/methodology/approach
A dynamic panel with 131 countries, including developed and developing ones, was utilized; the estimators of the generalized method of moments system (GMM system) model were selected because they have econometric characteristics more suitable for analysis, providing superior statistical precision compared to traditional linear estimation methods.
Findings
The results from the full panel suggest that concrete and well-defined institutions are important for financial development, confirming previous research, with a more limited scope than the present work.
Research limitations/implications
Limitations of this research include the availability of data for all countries worldwide, which would make the research broader and more complete.
Originality/value
A panel of countries was used, divided into developed and developing countries, to analyze the impact of institutional variables on the financial development of these countries, which is one of the differentiators of this work. Another differentiator of this research is the presentation of estimates in six different configurations, with emphasis on the GMM system model in one and two steps, allowing for comparison between results.
Keywords
Citation
Lisbinski, F.C. and Burnquist, H.L. (2024), "Institutions and financial development: Comparative analysis of developed and developing economies", EconomiA, Vol. 25 No. 2, pp. 347-376. https://doi.org/10.1108/ECON-11-2023-0201
Publisher
:Emerald Publishing Limited
Copyright © 2024, Fernanda Cigainski Lisbinski and Heloisa Lee Burnquist
License
Published in EconomiA. Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode
1. Introduction
Academic studies (Greenwood & Jovanovic, 1990; De Gregorio & Guidotti, 1995; Demirgüç-Kunt & Levine, 2001; Beck & Levine, 2004; Levine, 2005; Luintel, Khan, Arestis, & Theodoridis, 2008; Masoud & Hardaker, 2012; Allen, Gu, & Kowalewski, 2018; Fufa & Kim, 2018; Yang, 2019; Beck, 2020) have illustrated that a well-regulated, efficient financial system with a mature banking sector and capital markets has been essential for driving economic growth in several nations. A fundamental precept to explain this phenomenon is that financial intermediation allows, for example, the transfer of resources from economic agents willing to save to companies looking for investment opportunities. This makes it possible for companies to explore profitable opportunities and develop technological innovations, which cannot be realized without the necessary financial resources. Therefore, well-developed financial systems enable economic development in several ways, primarily through the efficient allocation of capital (Levine, 1997; Levine & Zervos, 1998; Beck, Levine, & Loayza, 2000; Rioja & Valev, 2004; Beck, 2020), the promotion of innovation (King & Levine, 1993; Huang & Xu, 1999; Pecé, Simona & Salisteanu, 2015; Rau, Wardrop, & Zingales, 2021) and the stimulation of savings (Arestis, Demetriades, & Luintel, 2001; Demirgüç-Kunt & Levine, 2001; Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt & Levine, 2004; Levine, 2005; Adeniyi, Omisakin, Egwaikhide, & Oyinlola, 2012; Bandura & Dzingirai, 2019). This makes an advanced financial system essential for the growth of economies (Thiel, 2001). In this sense, there has been increased interest in identifying the factors that explain such differences in financial performance among countries.
Institutional quality has been described as encompassing the existence of formal regulations, the effective implementation of these rules, and the trustworthiness of legal institutions (Acemoglu, 2010; Coase, 2012; La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, & Shleifer, 2013; Acemoglu, Gallego, & Robinson, 2014). At a macroeconomic level, financial development measures a country’s monetary, banking, and financial sector activities (Levine, 1997; Beck et al., 2000; Demetriades & Law, 2006; Chang, 2011; Van den Berg, 2016). Countries that have higher levels of financial development tend to have positive economic outcomes, such as prominent levels of economic growth and lower levels of inequality and poverty (Demirgüç-Kunt & Levine, 2001; Levine, 2005; Erol, Seven, Aydoğan, & Tunc, 2013; Coşkun, 2016) [1].
A factor of significant importance for financial systems to fulfill their role is the existence of institutions, such as government rules on human behavior and the structuring of social interactions. These factors are considered relevant for growth and economic development, helping explain successes and failures in resource allocation (Janvry & Sadoulet, 2020). Although their importance has been long recognized, they have gained visibility with the rise of New Institutional Economics (NIE), which explains the emergence of institutions as innovations to reduce market failures and transaction costs that result in adverse selection, moral hazard, and cooperation failures.
The importance of institutional resilience is evident because the implementation and enforcement of rules are essential for ensuring the credibility and confidence of markets, as well as for ensuring fair functioning and level playing in financial markets. In this regard, supervisory convergence, whereby supervisory practices are harmonized across jurisdictions, is vital to ensuring the fairness of regulatory burdens and limiting compliance costs (Ferran, 2012). In addition, full access to relevant information is essential for competent authorities to understand the dynamics within international groups during periods of stress (Acharya, 2009).
Studies (Levine & Zervos, 1998; Beck et al., 2000; Cull & Xu, 2005; Cline, 2010; Demirgüç-Kunt, 2012; Mazzucato & Wray, 2015) show that an operational and efficient financial system increases entrepreneurs' investment funds, which can help the development of the economy. In this sense, studies on the development of the financial market, such as effective policies and the rule of law, are fundamental, as they enable the identification and understanding of influential factors. Thus, adopting mitigating measures should be promoted in addition to strategic planning and practices by institutions, aiming to encourage financial development.
Therefore, this work investigates how institutional characteristics affect financial development, comparing developed and developing economies. Information from 131 countries during the period 2000–2021 was gathered to conduct empirical analyses of the impact of institutional factors in the form of indices for government accountability, political stability and absence of violence/terrorism, government effectiveness, corruption control, quality of the legal system, and economic freedom. This study sets itself apart from others through the categorization of countries into developed and developing nations and the application of various econometric models, including Ordinary Least Squares (OLS), fixed effects, random effects, and dynamic methods such as the Generalized Method of Moments (GMM). The aim is to provide a deeper and more comprehensive understanding of the relationships between institutional quality and financial development over the analyzed period. Including variables such as voice and accountability, political stability and absence of violence/terrorism, government effectiveness, regulatory quality, corruption control, and the rule of law, and employing dynamic models to tackle endogeneity stands out as a significant differentiator from existing literature.
Additionally, incorporating the voice and accountability variable, which considers the overall perception of institutional responsibility in credit provision, adds a subjective dimension to traditional analyses. This approach goes beyond objective metrics like interest rates or regulations, recognizing the importance of stakeholders' subjective opinions, which impact overall trust in a country’s economic environment, especially in the financial market. Thus, this research seeks to contribute theoretically and methodologically to understanding the factors driving financial development in specific economic contexts. It deepens the understanding of the interaction between institutional quality and financial development dynamics over time, bringing institutional variables into discussions that are often overlooked in economic growth and development analyses. The study hypothesizes that by comprehending the interdependence between institutions and finance, one can identify the crucial factors for improving economic and financial performance, particularly in developing countries, thereby creating an efficient and stable financial system based on the identified criteria.
This study is organized into five sections. The first section is the introduction, which aims to contextualize the topic. The second section presents a brief review of the literature on the subject. It presents previously conducted studies to explore the interrelationship between the development of the financial system and economic growth. The third section details the methods adopted to conduct this study. In the fourth section, the results are shown, discussed, and contextualized considering the literature. Finally, the fifth section addresses the conclusions drawn from the present research.
2. Connections between institutions, financial development, and economic growth
Financial development is a crucial topic for a country’s economic growth. The theoretical literature suggests that financial development plays a crucial role in economic growth by increasing the availability of capital and promoting improvements in the efficient allocation of financial resources. It also suggests that financial services contribute to industry expansion and economic growth (Kose, Prasad, Rogoff, & Wei, 2010; Bodie & Merton, 1998). Other authors also suggest that political economy and trade openness influence a country’s financial development (Andrianova, Demetriades, & Shortland, 2008; Baltagi, Egger, & Pfaffermayr, 2007; Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, & DemirgÜÇ-Kunt, 2001; Girma & Shortland, 2007; La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, & Vishny, 2000; Rajan & Zingales, 2003; Roe & Siegel, 2008). In other words, the development of the financial sector contributes to economic growth through both direct and indirect channels. In addition to financial services, the financial sector plays a highly crucial role as an indicator of profitable business opportunities and in improving corporate governance (Levine, 2005; Roubini & Sala-I-Martin, 1992).
Thus, the functions performed by the financial sector substantially influence the dynamics of economic growth rates (Gurley & Shaw, 1955; Patrick, 1966). An example is the study by Goldsmith (1969), which provides a relevant theoretical framework, suggesting that progress in financial development is associated with higher average economic growth rates. Demirgüç-Kunt and Levine (1996) also state that stock market development positively and robustly correlates with economic growth.
Given this, financial markets have contributed significantly to stimulating economic development through the influence of banks and stock exchanges, which encourage investment and the efficient allocation of resources. In this way, banks play a crucial role in granting credit and financing investment projects, allowing companies to expand their operations and drive economic growth. On the other hand, stock exchanges provide an environment for trading stocks and other financial assets, allowing companies to raise funds through initial public offerings (IPOs) and attracting investors to participate in capital markets. Thus, investment in companies and productive sectors has incentives, providing capital for expansion, innovation, and job creation (Bekaert, Harvey, & Lundblad, 2005; Taiwo & Falohun, 2016).
The role of financial development in economic growth is explained in theories that address financial structure. These theories are based on the behavior and interrelationship between banks, markets, and financial services and laws and finance, such as Financial Behavioral Theory (Kahneman & Tversky, 2013; Daniel, 2017; Richard et al., 2022), Asymmetric Information Theory (Akerlof, 1978; Stiglitz, 1985), Agency Theory (Jensen, 1993; Jensen & Meckling, 2019), the Theory of Corporate Finance (Myers, 1977; Fabozzi, Modigliani, & Jones, 2014; Miller, 1977), the Theory of Rational Expectations (Muth, 1961; Lucas, 1980; Barro, 1984), and the Theory of Law and Finance (Coase, 1990; La Porta, Lopez-De-Silanes, Shleifer, & Vishny, 1997, 2000; Levine, 2005).
The Theory of Law and Finance suggests that a legal system is fundamental to the success of the company, industry, and the national economy (La Porta et al., 1997; Levine, 1999). Thus, institutions, defined as legal and social rules and norms that govern economic systems and reward growth-promoting activities, play a crucial role in financial and economic development through diverse channels (Williamson, 1987; North, 1990; Acemoglu, Johnson, & Robinson, 2005). Financial markets and institutions effectively respond to technological and informational constraints within specific rules or institutions. Imperfections in financial markets, reflected in financial constraints, incomplete risk sharing, liquidity shortages, and inadequate market conditions, influence discipline in accumulating and allocating factors or capital (Acemoglu & Robinson, 2013). This dynamic has an intrinsic linkage with asymmetric information and transaction costs, in which well-developed institutions play a crucial role in improving the functioning of the economic and financial environment.
The fundamental mechanisms by which institutions can shape the relationship between financial development and economic growth include influencing property rights, contract enforcement, protection from the powerful elite, costs associated with contract enforcement, and economic policies, among other channels (Acemoglu & Robinson, 2013). Well-developed institutions are crucial in protecting the disadvantaged, ensuring property rights, and effectively enforcing contractual terms agreed upon between parties (Glaeser, Johnson, & Shleifer, 2001; Acemoglu & Johnson, 2005). In addition, by acting in defense of the interests of the less favored parties, such institutions guarantee protection to minority shareholders against privileged information held by more informed shareholders or managers through property rights and countermeasures against the powerful elite. This logic can also be extended to safeguarding the interests of creditors against the risks of expropriation and asymmetric information and protecting depositors and borrowers against monopoly power (Modigliani & Perotti, 1997; Ewert & Wagenhofer, 2011).
More vital institutions can prevent noncompliance with contractual obligations and the withdrawal of commitments established between parties by employing compromise mechanisms and independent arbitrators. The availability of these services can be costly due to the inherent complexity of financial contracts or the inefficiency of courts and regulators. Therefore, quality institutions play a crucial role in mitigating this challenge by contributing to the sustainability of financial development and lending (Acemoglu & Johnson, 2005).
Another crucial channel through which institutions affect the relationship between finance and economic growth is economic policy. Institutions play a crucial role in shaping macroeconomic and financial policy, primarily through the government budgeting process and central banks' and financial supervisors' degree of independence and accountability. This necessitates a combination of policies that includes macroeconomics, regulation, competition policy, and financial openness. These elements can be associated with macroeconomic instabilities and regulatory failures that, in turn, impact financial development and economic growth (Mishkin, 1999; Boyd & De Nicolo, 2005). Therefore, well-developed institutions ensure financial systems and more robust growth in the future by fostering sound economic policies.
La Porta et al. (1997), La Porta, Lopez‐de‐Silanes, Shleifer, and Vishny (1998, 2000) investigated the relationship between investor protection (in terms of legal rules and quality of law enforcement), capital markets (encompassing equity and debt markets), and the concentration of ownership in publicly traded companies. They concluded that the legal approach is crucial to understanding corporate governance and its potential reforms. Subsequently, Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Levine (2003) advanced this work by showing a rigid/flexible link between legal origins and financial development. On the other hand, Acemoglu, Aghion, and Zilibotti (2006) and Anderlini, Felli, Immordino, and Riboni (2013) showed that a legal environment that is too rigid can obstruct economic development, exerting a negative impact on financial development.
For authors such as Douglas North (1990), institutions are significant in financial development and define the rules to be followed (“the rules of the game”), including constitutions and laws, codes of conduct, and standards of behavior in a country; this is crucial for the process of economic growth. In this way, solid institutions explain financial development, especially in the banking and finance sector; if there is no well-defined institutional environment, there is an obstacle to the growth of the economy (Demetriades & Law, 2006).
Thus, high institutional quality helps the development and maintenance of financial markets (Konadu-Agyemang, 2018) so that if the development of financial institutions and the market occurs, there is an increase in the quantity of monetary services and the stimulation of economic evolution (Patrick, 1966). Thus, the development of the financial sector instigates economic growth as the economy approaches economic-financial equilibrium. However, as financial development progresses, the first impact on supply diminishes, and demand begins to keep pace with the financial growth of a country’s economy (Patrick, 1966). Thus, developing countries need reforms in their financial systems. On the other hand, underdeveloped countries need sudden changes in their financial systems to achieve a well-performing financial structure.
Finally, it is essential to note that a country’s financial system influences savings and investment decisions, critical determinants of long-term economic growth. As far as the country is concerned, government policies and legislation can help mobilize savings. More transparent government policies and legislation promoting greater information disclosure can help individuals and companies make informed investment decisions (Anwar & Cooray, 2012). At the international level, financial globalization can contribute to a better allocation of financial resources. Chinn and Ito (2006) argue that countries with a higher degree of legal and institutional development are better positioned to receive financial liberalization help. Given this, the degree to which financial development affects economic growth also depends mainly on the quality of governance.
Thus, this paper examines how these institutional conditions influence the level of financial development in developed and developing economies, examining the relationships among financial development, institutions, and economic growth. This research is based on the variables provided by the World Bank’s Worldwide Governance Indicators (WGI), which aim to measure and understand the impact of institutional quality and governance on countries' financial and economic development.
2.1 Literature review
The most recent empirical literature, primarily based on regressions of panel data, has shown that the financial system is significantly affected by institutional norms. According to North (1990), institutions are significant in financial development and define the rules to be followed, including constitutions and laws, codes of conduct, and the standard of behavior to be followed in a country; these criteria are recognized as crucial for the process of economic growth and development. Knack and Keefer (1995) corroborate the role of institutional quality in improving financial development. Other studies show that government-run banking, the political economy, and trade openness influence financial development (Andrianova et al., 2008; Baltagi et al., 2007; Beck et al., 2001; Girma & Shortland, 2007; La Porta et al., 2000; Rajan & Zingales, 2003; Roe & Siegel, 2008).
Law and Demetriades (2006) analyzed whether the interaction between institutional quality and financial development positively influences economic growth when considered separately. They used dynamic panel data techniques for 43 developing countries from 1980–2001 to do this. The results suggested that trade openness, including capital flows and institutions, is a determinant and essential factor for the financial development of middle-income countries but is weaker in low-income countries.
Sghaier and Abida (2013) examined the causal relationships between foreign direct investment (FDI), financial development, and economic growth in a panel of 4 North African countries (Tunisia, Morocco, Algeria, and Egypt), for the period 1980–2011. To do this, the authors used a panel data analysis with the generalized method of moments (GMM), finding robust evidence of a positive relationship between FDI and economic growth. They also found evidence that the development of the domestic financial system is an essential prerequisite for FDI to affect economic growth positively. Thus, it was possible to conclude that the development of a domestic financial system needs to be driven by local reforms to maximize the benefits of the presence of FDI.
Anwar and Cooray (2012) verified the impact of the interaction between (1) financial development and foreign direct investment and (2) financial development and the quality of governance on economic growth in South Asia. To do so, the authors used panel data from 1970 to 2009. The results suggest that quality institutions affect the level of financial development, implying that the extent of development benefits depends on the quality of governance. In addition, indicators for the rule of law, or more specifically, the guarantee of political rights and civil liberties, increase economic and financial development. Thus, financial development has contributed to increased FDI benefits in South Asia. In addition, improved political rights and civil liberties have increased the benefits of financial development in South Asia.
Arcand, Berkes, and Panizza (2015) and Cecchetti and Kharroubi (2015) demonstrated that better financial sector development can be an obstacle to real economic growth. The quality of institutions affects foreign direct investment (FDI) and trade openness in diverse ways. Raza, Shah, and Ali (2019) corroborates these findings by analyzing foreign direct investment (FDI) and economic growth in the presence of a sound governance system in the countries of the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). Using a dataset covering the years 1996 to 2013, fixed effects models and the GMM estimator were used. The study’s results revealed that regulatory quality, control of corruption, political stability, voice and accountability, and government effectiveness had significant positive associations with economic growth. The authors concluded that the more countries maintain their institutional quality, the better their economic growth and FDI flows will be.
Rani and Kumar (2019) investigated the long-term association and direction of causality between economic growth, trade openness, and gross capital formation in Brazil, Russia, India, China, and South Africa (BRICS). To this end, the authors used the autoregressive distributed lag model (ARDL) and the vector error correction (VEC) model to examine the long-term associations and the causal relationships between concurrent variables. The results of the ARDL limit tests indicated a long-term relationship between economic growth, trade openness, and gross capital formation. Granger’s causal test revealed unidirectional causality between trade openness and economic growth in India and that Brazil supports the trade-led growth hypothesis. In contrast, two-way causality is found between China’s trade openness and economic growth. In addition, empirical evidence of unidirectional causality between economic growth and trade openness is found in South Africa, confirming the growth-led trade hypothesis. Thus, trade openness significantly determines economic growth in BRICS countries.
Nguyen (2019) studied the effects of financial deepening on growth and productivity dynamics in an economy where heterogeneous entrepreneurs face endogenous debt constraints. From this, the author concluded that low-quality institutions hinder foreign investment and limit the positive impact of trade openness on economic growth. However, when the quality of institutions increases, the positive effect of FDI on the economy is amplified, generating additional benefits beyond the direct effects of trade openness.
Khan, Peng, and Li (2019) analyzed the relationship between institutional quality and financial development in developing and emerging countries. They used a panel dataset from 189 countries, employing OLS dynamics, fixed effects, random effects models, and GMM method estimators. The results indicated that better institutions are essential for financial development; particularly, stability, corruption control, and regulatory quality policies positively affect financial development worldwide. The rule of law negatively affects financial development, which reveals that in most global countries, the rule of law is fragile. Controlling the corruption ratio positively affects financial development in emerging countries, which indicates that most countries have reduced corruption to a low level. Thus, the study suggests that developing and emerging countries should improve institutional quality by re-examining the rules of law, government effectiveness, and government accountability. Nguyen (2019) studied the effects of financial deepening on growth and productivity dynamics in an economy where heterogeneous entrepreneurs face endogenous debt constraints. From this, the author concluded that low-quality institutions hinder foreign investment and limit the positive impact of trade openness on economic growth. However, when the quality of institutions increases, the positive effect of FDI on the economy is amplified, generating additional benefits beyond the direct effects of trade openness.
Abaidoo and Agyapong (2022) examine how institutional quality influences variability in financial development among sub-Saharan African (SSA) economies. They used the maximum likelihood of limited information (LIML) as an estimation technique to do so. The results suggested that institutional quality increases the pace of financial development among the economies of the subregion. In a further analysis at the micro level, where the components of the institutional quality index were examined separately, the results of the study suggested that effective governance, regulatory quality, the rule of law, and accountability tend to have a positive and significant impact on the development of the financial sector.
Asante, Takyi, and Mensah (2023) analyzed the effects of financial development on economic growth in sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) using a panel of 29 countries covering the period from 2000 to 2019. The System GMM model was used to estimate the model. The authors found that financial development positively and significantly affects economic growth. Moreover, when the rule of law, political stability, and regulatory quality are highly effective, there is a positive effect on financial development and economic growth.
3. Methodology
3.1 The empirical model
In this work, a panel data model is used to analyze the relationship between the quality of institutions and financial development for developed and developing countries and for the complete set of countries in the sample. Based on empirical studies and theoretical aspects, variables and indicators were identified to define an empirical model aiming to explain the availability of domestic financing in the countries included in the analysis. The model is defined by Equation (1).
The dependent variable was chosen to represent the availability of credit in the markets of each country according to the “supply-leading” hypothesis developed by Patrick (1966), according to which there is a causal relationship between financial development and economic growth. In this way, increasing financial markets and regulatory quality would result in a more excellent supply of financial services, leading to real economic growth. Therefore, it can be understood that the greater the availability of credit to the private sector is, the greater the levels of savings and investment, which promotes efficiency in the accumulation of capital, stimulating the expansion of the economic system and its contribution to the country’s economy.
3.2 Econometric approach
This study uses a dynamic panel approach that includes 131 countries, including all countries in the sample, in the form of a panel composed only of developed countries and another with developing countries. The approach used was the Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) model developed by Arellano and Bond (1991), more specifically, the GMM model developed by Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundell and Bond (1998), and the Dynamic Generalized Method of Moments (DGMM) recommended by Holtz-Eakin, Newey, and Rosen (1988). Other linear procedures, such as OLS, fixed effect, and random effect analyses, were adopted to estimate the model to compare and evaluate the results between models.
The DGMM model proposed by Arellano and Bond (1991) provides superior statistical accuracy to traditional linear estimation methods because it considers that the coefficients are variable in time, in addition to selecting the lags and periods ahead that are important for estimating specific coefficients. As a result, the data are used more effectively, resulting in more reliable and accurate estimates. Additionally, as the dynamic part of the system is considered, the estimates are not biased by problems of omitted variables or parameter instability, allowing the use of long-term information in the estimates. Thus, the main advantage of the DGMM model is that it allows efficient estimation of dynamic models, even when the underlying model is highly nonlinear and involves heteroscedastic disturbances. It also allows for consistent estimation of coefficients even in the presence of autocorrelation and produces standard errors that consider estimation bias due to time dependence. However, the System GMM is superior to the DGMM.
According to Arellano and Bover (1995), the System GMM model has advantages over the DGMM model:
Reduced bias. The System GMM model is less biased than the DGMM model because it uses the first differences and the levels of the variables as instruments. This helps to solve the problem of weak instruments, which can lead to biased estimates in the DGMM model.
Increased efficiency. The System GMM model is also more efficient than the DGMM model because it uses more information in the estimation process. This is because the System GMM model can estimate short-term and long-term coefficients, while the DGMM model can estimate only short-term coefficients.
Robustness to incorrect specification. The System GMM model is more robust to specification errors than the DGMM model is. This is because the System GMM model uses the first differences and the level variables as instruments, which helps to mitigate the effects of poor specification.
The System GMM model is a more robust and efficient estimator than the DGMM model and is the preferred method for estimating dynamic panel data models.
To analyze and obtain the best results, we estimated the OLS, DGMM, and System GMM models; however, the focus was on the System GMM model, which provides a more efficient estimator than the others. Thus, the results are interpreted based on the System GMM estimates.
In these models, the two-step estimator is more efficient than the one-step estimator. However, Monte Carlo studies have proven that the efficiency gain is small, and the two-step estimator slowly converges to its asymptotic distribution. On the other hand, in finite samples, the asymptotic standard errors associated with the two-step GMM estimator can be tendentiously low (Blundell & Bond, 1998), while the results of OLS estimates, according to Hoeffler (2002), present a coefficient with an upward bias
The System GMM model controls for the endogeneity of the independent variables, considering that the institutional structure is influenced by the interaction between financial market development and institutional quality and other common factors that may have been omitted. Thus, the model is defined as follows:
For the estimation of the model, the logarithmic transformation was applied to the variables to facilitate the interpretation of the estimated coefficients as proportional effects associated with each of them.
3.3 Model data and variables
The data used for model estimation are from secondary sources. The data were obtained from the World Bank’s Worldwide Governance Indicators (WGI) database and the Fraser Institute (2023). The variables that make up the model are as follows:
Domestic credit: This is the dependent variable and represents the proportion of credit granted by banks to the private sector about the size of the economy. Credit availability facilitates investments in expansion, innovation, and employability (Demirgüç-Kunt & Levine, 2001; Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, & Levine, 2004). Trust in this environment is strongly influenced by sound institutions, including clear regulations, an effective legal system, and robust corporate governance (North, 1990). These elements foster safe financial transactions, encouraging banks to increase their lending activities; therefore, this variable was used as a proxy for countries' financial development.
Voice and accountability: voice and accountability can affect overall confidence in a country’s economic environment, influencing banks' willingness to extend credit (World Bank, 2023). Solid institutions play a role in trust and responsibility that permeates economic agents' perception, influencing their decision to lend and invest. When the view of accountability is positive, an environment conducive to financial development is created since trust is essential to mobilizing financial resources (Putnam, 1993).
Political stability and the absence of violence/terrorism: When a country establishes a stable political environment characterized by reduced uncertainty and the absence of violent conflicts, it creates a favorable scenario for credit. This political stability fosters investor confidence and encourages banks to increase their lending activities to the private sector (Yang, 2011; Asongu, 2014; Raza et al., 2019). Thus, strong and well-developed institutions, facilitated by a stable policy environment, are critical for the efficient functioning of financial markets. They provide a reliable framework for conducting business, ensuring the protection of property rights and the effective enforcement of contracts (North, 1990).
Government effectiveness: An effective government could implement policies that promote economic stability and competent oversight, creating an environment conducive to financial development. When banks perceive effective governance, they may feel more confident in granting credit because government effectiveness suggests that implementing policy measures benefits economic growth (Minniti, 2008; Zhou, Bao, Zhao, He, Cui, & Liu, 2022; Khan et al., 2019).
Regulatory quality: Clear and well-defined regulations create a predictable environment for financial institutions, fostering stability and economic order. The predictability provided by good regulatory quality is a crucial element for companies to plan strategically and confidently make investment decisions (Smit, 2010). Regulatory quality is a fundamental component, as it guides the behavior of economic agents, contributing to an efficient institutional environment (North, 1990). In addition, regulatory quality encourages banks to lend more, clarifying the operating environment (Laeven & Valencia, 2020; Khan et al., 2019).
Corruption control: The presence of elevated levels of corruption can be detrimental to the domestic credit environment, introducing uncertainty and additional risks for banks. Authors such as Raza et al. (2019), Khan et al. (2019), and Song, Chang, and Gong (2021) state that low levels of corruption are associated with a more stable and credit-friendly environment. Corruption undermines the efficiency of financial markets and investor confidence and increases risk perception. In contrast, effective control of corruption contributes to a more transparent and predictable environment by encouraging banks to lend more to the private sector (Julius Otusanya, 2011; Admati, 2017).
Rule of law: A robust legal environment characterized by a strong rule of law lays the foundation for legal certainty, where contracts are respected, and legal disputes are resolved fairly. Such legal stability creates a scenario conducive to the efficient functioning of financial markets. By perceiving a reliable legal system, banks can gain greater confidence in granting credit since they have the assurance that agreements will be fulfilled and that legal issues will be dealt with equitably (La Porta et al., 1997; Beck et al., 2003; Laeven & Valencia, 2020).
Economic freedom: Economic freedom contributes to a more dynamic business environment by stimulating economic growth, creating more accessible and more competitive environments favoring efficiency and innovation, and creating business opportunities that, in turn, can boost lending by banks (Acemoglu et al., 2005; La Porta, Lopez‐de‐Silanes, Shleifer, & Vishny, 1999). According to Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, Laeven, and Maksimovic (2006) and Levine (2005), greater economic freedom is often associated with more developed financial systems in which banks play a crucial role in financing business activities.
Population: A larger population can indicate a broader market for banks, creating opportunities to expand financial services. In this context, efficient institutions are crucial in facilitating access to credit on a larger population scale, boosting investment, and enabling a nation’s economic growth (Levine, 1997; King & Levine, 1993).
Gross savings: Higher savings can indicate a greater volume of financial resources available to be directed at investments and loans, stimulating economic growth (Rajan & Zingales, 2003). On the other hand, it is essential to note that if people are saving more, they may, in return, invest less in immediate consumption, which may have implications for aggregate demand in the economy (Agénor, 2003; Su, Xu, & Tong, 2023).
Gross domestic product: A more robust economy, reflected by GDP, not only suggests a more remarkable ability to pay but also creates an environment conducive to investment opportunities. Banks sensing a growing economy tend to feel more confident in providing credit to the private sector, as economic expansion indicates a potential demand for financing. As an indicator of the size and overall health of the economy, GDP directly influences the scale and prospects of credit (Panizza & Presbitero, 2013; Valickova, Havranek, & Horvath, 2015; Khan et al., 2019).
Foreign direct investment: The influx of capital from FDI can significantly impact the resources available for banks to borrow. The inflow of foreign investment not only provides an additional source of financing for financial institutions but can also indicate the confidence of foreign investors in the stability and economic growth potential of the recipient country, generating a positive influence of FDI on credit dynamics (Levine, 2005; De Haas & Van Lelyveld, 2006; Claessens & Van Horen, 2012).
Thus, Table 1 presents information regarding the variables that make up the model, highlighting the source of the data collection, period of analysis, expected signs, and underlying theoretical foundation. This approach provides clarity and facilitates the interpretation of the study results.
The analysis period spans from approximately 2000 to 2021, a time series of 21 years. The criteria for including the available data were as follows: the initial data from 2000 were published annually, and the data from 2021 were the most recent data available in the databases researched. The sample includes 131 countries for which data for the selected variables were presented.
4. Presentation and analysis of the results
In the context of GMM panel models, conducting unit root tests is of paramount importance for assessing the stationarity of the time series employed in the investigation. Stationarity represents a fundamental condition to ensure the validity and reliability of the estimates obtained. In situations where time series are non-stationary, meaning they exhibit a unit root, the results from GMM estimations may be biased or inconsistent, as evidenced by Arellano and Bond (1991) and Baltagi (2008). Based on this premise, the Levin, Lin, and Chu (LLC) (2002) and Harris-Tzavalis (HT) tests were conducted at levels, as well as after applying the logarithmic transformation. Conducting two unit root tests, such as the LLC and HT tests, aims to increase the robustness and reliability of the conclusions drawn. Each test has its own characteristics and underlying assumptions, and employing multiple tests allows verifying whether the results are consistent across different analysis methods. Therefore, by conducting two distinct tests, it is possible to reduce reliance on a single test and obtain a more comprehensive assessment of the stationarity of the time series in question. This helps mitigate potential specification errors and increase confidence in the conclusions drawn from the unit root tests (Stock & Watson, 2020).
The results of the LLC test using the variables at levels indicated the presence of a unit root for the variables related to Political Stability and Absence of Violence/Terrorism (
The serial correlation tests in Table 2 ruled out first-order serial correlation (AR1) and indicated the absence of second-order serial correlation (AR2). Importantly, when performing the first differentiation, the serial correlation AR (1) was used when the temporal component of the variable and the level error term were not serially correlated (Arellano & Bond, 1991). However, the GMM estimator is consistent only when the second-order correlation is not significant, even if the first-order correlation is not equal to zero (Abdullah, Habibullah, & Baharumshah, 2009). According to Arellano and Bond (1991), the autocorrelation of RA (1) is expected to be negatively significant; on the other hand, the second-order AR autocorrelation test (2) should not be significant; this is the crucial point about the validity of the instruments. Given this, the first- and second-order serial correlation tests were all satisfactory. The Sargan test demonstrated that the instruments used for the estimations of the System GMM model are valid, as it did not reject the null hypothesis and, therefore, presents a robust model and consistent and unbiased standard error. Thus, the analysis can be performed based on the results of GMM estimates (Khan et al., 2019). Regarding Hausman’s test, he noted that the fixed effects estimator is preferable to the random effects model, as it rejects the null hypothesis at the 5% level of statistical significance. In addition, the Wald tests performed on the models indicated the presence of heteroscedasticity, as they rejected the null hypothesis at the 5% level of statistical significance, and it was necessary to estimate these hypotheses in a robust format.
Table 2 shows the models' results in relation to the different panels. The variable domestic credit to the private sector by banks (% of GDP) in the first lag (
These results show the importance of domestic credit to the private sector by banks as a significant determinant of credit granted to the private sector. They also show that an increase in credit in the previous period has a positive and significant effect on subsequent credit, highlighting the influence of this factor on financial market dynamics and its impact on the private sector (Stepanyan & Guo, 2011; Korkmaz, 2015).
The variable political stability (
The indicator of political stability used has undergone variations throughout the series analyzed, having gone through several periods, such as the 2008 crisis, the debt crisis in Europe in 2009, and COVID-19 in 2020. In this way, there are reasons why political stability hurts the provision of credit to the private sector. First, political instability creates uncertainty and risk for lenders, making them more cautious when extending credit. Investors and lenders may be reluctant to undertake long-term financing or make significant investments in an environment where political stability is absent. In addition, political instability can disrupt economic policies, create regulatory uncertainties, and harm the business environment, discouraging banks from providing credit to the private sector (Alesina, Özler, Roubini, & Swagel, 1996; Aisen & Veiga, 2013; Tuncay, 2018). It is essential to highlight here the importance of considering the particularities of each economic context and country and conducting complementary analyses for a more comprehensive understanding of this complex relationship between political stability and credit granting.
The variable Effective Government (
The regulatory quality variable
Therefore, regulatory quality is crucial in granting credit to the private sector. A favorable regulatory environment with clear and transparent policies can encourage banks to increase the credit supply. Effective and well-implemented regulations offer security and reliability to the financial system, decreasing the risks associated with lending. In addition, good regulatory quality can be related to policies that stimulate economic growth and private sector development, creating an environment conducive to investment and entrepreneurship (Love & Zicchino, 2006; Laeven & Valencia, 2020).
The rule of law variable was
The variable population (
An increase in a country’s population usually implies a higher demand for goods and services, economic growth, and business activity. Thus, banks respond to this demand by expanding their credit supply to meet the needs of the private sector. In addition, population growth is related to economic development and the expansion of the private sector, creating a favorable environment for granting credit (Demirgüç-Kunt & Huizinga, 2010; Stepanyan & Guo, 2011; Asiamah et al., 2021).
The savings variable (
In this context, the increase in domestic savings implies the availability of resources for individuals and companies to save or invest, reducing the credit search. This leads to more cautious behavior about spending and investments, decreasing the demand for loans. Additionally, an increase in domestic savings may reflect greater risk aversion or economic uncertainty, causing individuals and businesses to prefer to keep their savings as a safety reserve, ceasing to invest or borrow. This conservative stance on credit reduces the demand for loans, decreasing credit to the private sector (Agénor, 2003; Su et al., 2023).
The variable GDP (
This result can be justified by the economic growth that stimulates the demand for financing, better payment prospects caused by a healthy economy, and increased confidence in economic agents. An expanding GDP indicates a growing economy, increasing the need for credit for investment, consumption, and enterprises. In addition, a favorable economic environment improves borrowers' ability to repay and builds confidence in banks to extend credit (Panizza & Presbitero, 2013; Valickova et al., 2015).
In addition, the variables Voice and Accountability
Economic Freedom showed statistical significance in the OLS, RE, DGMM, and System GMM (one-step) models, with negative impacts of 0.35, 0.29, 2.84, and 0.96%, respectively. This finding indicates that excessive economic restrictions and government interventions may limit economic agents' ability to make investment decisions and seek credit (Acemoglu, 2005; Roychowdhury et al., 2019). Finally, Foreign Direct Investment did not show statistical significance in any of the models; however, it is important to highlight that foreign direct investment (FDI) plays an essential role in a country’s financial development and credit expansion. The capital injection associated with FDI strengthens local financial markets, allowing financial institutions to expand their credit supply. The entry of foreign financial institutions diversifies the financial system and introduces best practices and abilities, promoting efficiency and stability. This transfer of knowledge and experience enhances the ability to assess risks, resulting in more robust lending practices. In addition, FDI-generated competition encourages innovation and improves the quality of financial services, contributing to financial inclusion (Levine, 2005; De Haas & Van Lelyveld, 2006; Claessens & Van Horen, 2012).
4.1 Results of the system GMM for developed and developing countries of the world
Table 3 shows that the GMM estimator is appropriate for parameter estimation. The empirical results provide relevant statistical evidence and are subject to specific contingencies, i.e. depending on different conditions and contexts. Thus, it is observed that the variable domestic credit granted to the private sector by banks (% of GDP) in the first lag (
The variable political stability
The variable Government Effectiveness (
The variable regulatory quality (
The positive impact of regulatory quality on credit granting between developed and developing countries can be justified due to the robustness of regulatory institutions and the business environment. A higher regulatory quality strengthens bank confidence, promoting positive lending. However, when regulatory quality is poor, legal uncertainty and a lack of confidence result, leading to a negative impact on the granting of credit by banks. This highlights the importance of a stable and effective regulatory environment for the financial sector and economic development (Klapper et al., 2006; Chen, Li, Liu, & Zhou, 2021).
The coefficient of the corruption control variable (
Notably, this corruption control indicator has values ranging from −2.5 to 2.5; thus, positive indicators show that anticorruption laws are more effective, while negative indicators indicate that anticorruption laws are less effective and, therefore, open the door to increased corruption. Most of the countries that make up the sample have a historical series with negative indicators, which may explain the negative sign of the corruption control coefficient (Kaufmann, Kraay, & Mastruzzi, 2011). For Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2001), structural changes in the world and governments may not ensure the effectiveness of control; the greater the number of such changes is, the greater the degree to which corruption is, and the greater the extent to which the application of such measures ends up reducing the supply of financing.
Corruption breeds uncertainty and a lack of business confidence, discouraging banks from providing credit. This is because corruption increases credit risk by directing loans to less viable projects or companies, which results in a greater likelihood of default. In addition, corruption distorts the regulatory and legal environment and undermines the effective enforcement of laws and regulations. This leads to a lack of protection of property rights, making contracts less secure and increasing the risk for creditors. Systemic corruption makes it difficult for banks to enforce the terms of contracts or recover their investments. Finally, corruption undermines economic efficiency and resource allocation, diverting financial resources to lower-productivity projects to benefit companies or individuals with political connections. This limits and hinders access to credit for innovative companies, entrepreneurs, and productive sectors, slowing economic development (Pellegrini & Gerlagh, 2004; Fernández-Torres, Gutiérrez-Fernández, & Ramajo-Hernández, 2018).
The population variable
The coefficient of the saving variable (
The variable GDP (
Therefore, the model estimates showed that institutional-related variables have more influence in developing countries than in developed countries. According to Sahay et al. (2015), financial development increases resilience. It boosts economic growth, especially in emerging and developing economies, by mobilizing savings, promoting information sharing, efficient resource allocation, and easing diversification and risk management. Thus, developing countries with weaker and less effective institutions can generate uncertainty and need more confidence in business, directly affecting credit granting. Given this, the importance of strengthening institutions in these countries to improve access to credit and boost economic growth and development is highlighted, generating more robust and more developed institutions that enable security in credit negotiations. Finally, by analyzing how institutions affect the efficiency and stability of financial systems, this study provides relevant information for improving public policies, identifying specific obstacles faced by different types of economies, and promoting a sounder and more efficient financial environment.
5. Conclusion
This study examined the role of institutional quality in financial development in both developed and developing economies. To do this, data from a dynamic panel analysis were used for a sample of 131 countries worldwide; these data were first applied to the combined sample and a set of developed and developing countries separately. The analysis showed that in developing economies, the variables of institutions used exert more significant influence on the granting of credit by banks to the private sector and the financial development of these countries. These results agree with the related academic literature.
However, in developed economies, the lack of significance of these variables can be explained by the fact that in advanced economies, where institutions are more robust, variations in institutional quality may have a less pronounced impact. In addition, in developed economies, institutions may be more resilient to change, and other factors, such as technological innovation and human capital, may have greater relevance in explaining growth disparities.
The findings of this research suggest that governments in developing countries, as well as credit regulators, adopt better-defined, concrete, and transparent governance structures since the impact of these variables in these countries is significant. In this way, good governance and the definition of quality institutions are fundamental for the financial development of these countries, leading to economic growth and development and improving the quality of life of local populations.
The limitations of this research include the availability of data for all countries in the world, which would make the research broader and more complete. Future studies could deepen the understanding of the causal link between economic growth and financial development, including variables of inequality and income, to better capture the effects of corruption or to conduct separate analyses of emerging and developing countries.
Description of the model variables
Variable | Description | Source | Year | Expected signal | Theoretical basis |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Domestic lending to the private sector by banks (% of GDP) | World Bank | 2000–2021 | + | Stepanyan and Guo (2011), Korkmaz (2015), Khan et al. (2019) | |
Voice and Accountability | WGI – World Bank | 2000–2021 | + | Yang (2011), Asongu (2014), Raza et al. (2019) | |
Political Stability and Absence of Violence/Terrorism | WGI – World Bank | 2000–2021 | + | Raza et al. (2019), Khan et al. (2019), Mensah, Kofi Osei-Fosu, and Nkansah Asante (2023) | |
Effective Government | WGI – World Bank | 2000–2021 | + | Minniti (2008), Zhou et al. (2022), Khan et al. (2019) | |
Regulatory Quality | WGI – World Bank | 2000–2021 | + | Laeven and Valencia (2020), Khan et al. (2019) | |
Control of Corruption | WGI – World Bank | 2000–2021 | + | Raza et al. (2019), Khan et al. (2019), Song et al. (2021) | |
Rule of Law | WGI – World Bank | 2000–2021 | + | Beck and Levine (2001), Khan et al. (2019), Mensah et al. (2023) | |
Economic Freedom | Fraser Institute | 2000–2021 | + | Acemoglu (2005), Roychowdhury, Shroff, and Verdi (2019) | |
Population | World Bank | 2000–2021 | + | Stepanyan and Guo (2011), Khan et al. (2019), Asiamah, Steel, and Ackah (2021) | |
Gross Savings | World Bank | 2000–2021 | – | Agénor (2003), Su et al. (2023) | |
Gross domestic product | World Bank | 2000–2021 | + | Panizza and Presbitero (2013), Valickova et al. (2015), Khan et al. (2019) | |
Foreign Direct Investment | World Bank | 2000–2021 | + | Levine (2005), De Haas and Van Lelyveld (2006), Claessens and Van Horen (2012) |
Source(s): Prepared by the authors, 2023
Effects of institutional quality factors on financial development – dependent variable (
Variables | OLS | FE | RE | DGMM | GMM (one-step system) | GMM (two-step system) |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
_ | _ | _ | 0.28080*** | 0.24390*** | 0.46109*** | |
(0.07854) | (0.07189) | (0.15359) | ||||
−0.00029 | −0.00303 | −0.00153 | −0.00045 | 0.00910 | 0.01600 | |
(0.00628) | (0.00600) | (0.00627) | (0.00368) | (0.01458) | (0.01064) | |
−0.00749 | −0.00745 | −0.00831 | −0.01208*** | −0.01494 | −0.01691* | |
(0.00581) | (0.00862) | (0.00650) | (0.002555) | (0.01514) | (0.00875) | |
0.00682 | 0.01791* | 0.01014 | 0.02506 | 0.01762 | 0.05392** | |
(0.01287) | (0.01688) | (0.01555) | (0.01918) | (0.02748) | (0.02027) | |
0.01891* | 0.01797* | 0.01629* | 0.01889* | 0.01457 | 0.07012* | |
(0.01140) | (0.01113) | (0.00981) | (0.01411) | (0.01722) | (0.01941) | |
−0.01128* | −0.00365 | −0.01185 | −0.00501 | −0.02455 | 0.00976 | |
(0.00728) | (0.01239) | (0.01265) | (0.00767) | (0.02084) | (0.01811) | |
−0.01981* | −0.0231763 | −0.02188 | −0.02122 | 0.01002 | −0.05191** | |
(0.01343) | (0.0230548) | (0.02033) | (0.02520) | (0.03033) | (0.02628) | |
−0.34871** | 0.20623 | −0.29833* | −2.83418*** | −0.96091* | −0.64085 | |
(0.15888) | (0.35223) | (0.21956) | (0.89070) | (0.60937) | (0.62461) | |
0.18681*** | −1.52172 | 0.15645* | 0.44686 | −0.03845 | 0.21087* | |
(0.06683) | (1.44957) | (0.11468) | (0.34937) | (0.23322) | (0.18958) | |
−0.03716*** | −0.05338* | −0.04086* | −0.07181 | −0.03547 | −0.07964** | |
(0.01472) | (0.04366) | (0.02848) | (0.055181) | (0.04407) | (0.04148) | |
0.03483** | 0.04132* | −0.02451 | 0.08649*** | 0.03722 | 0.03678* | |
(0.01741) | (0.03659) | (0.02665) | (0.02992) | (0.06561) | (0.07482) | |
−0.00088 | 0.0064694 | 0.0040635 | 0.0256498 | −0.08707 | 0.026953 | |
(0.03666) | (0.0866287) | (0.0642394) | (0.0407629) | (0.11965) | (0.16569) | |
Const. | 22.49587*** | 44.75713 | 22.45786*** | – | −7.00853 | −16.25145 |
(0.76316) | (2.32335) | (1.35846) | (2.63368) | (1.62246) | ||
N. Obs. | 411 | 411 | 411 | 370 | 370 | 370 |
Tests | ||||||
Hausman | – | 20.00 | – | – | – | |
(0.0454) | ||||||
Breusch‒Pagan (heteroscedasticity) | 29.74 | 31.45 | 38.94 | – | – | – |
(0.0000) | (0.0009) | (0.0001) | ||||
AR1 | – | – | – | −3.283 | −4.83 | −7.69 |
(0.0010) | (0.0000) | (0.0000) | ||||
AR2 | – | – | – | −0.19299 | −0.89 | 0.10 |
(0.8470) | (0.376) | (0.921) | ||||
Sargan | – | – | – | 57.8097 | 43.53 | 43.53 |
(0.2694) | (0.182) | (0.182) |
Note(s): The values in parentheses are the results of standard errors, and * is the significance level of the variable being 10: *, 5: **, 1%: ***. In the section referring to tests, the values in parentheses are the p values of the calculated statistics
Source(s): Prepared by the authors, 2023
Results of the system GMM for developed and developing countries around the world – dependent variable (
Variables | GMM (two-step system) all countries | GMM (two-step system) developed countries | GMM (two-step system) developing countries |
---|---|---|---|
0.46109*** | 0.50496*** | 2.79394* | |
(0.15359) | (0.05498) | (1.49474) | |
0.01600 | −0.00271 | −0.38491 | |
(0.01064) | (0.00907) | (0.20547) | |
−0.01691* | −0.00583 | −0.08204 | |
(0.00875) | (0.00817) | (0.06369) | |
0.05392** | 0.02232 | 0.31248* | |
(0.02027) | (0.03025) | (0.17345) | |
0.07012* | 0.00654 | 0.66306* | |
(0.01941) | (0.02679) | (0.35522) | |
0.00976 | 0.00912 | −0.662137* | |
(0.01811) | (0.02138) | (0.40607) | |
0.05191** | 0.00141 | 0.06368 | |
(0.02628) | (0.02885) | (0.06992) | |
−0.64085 | −1.64706 | 9.90022 | |
(0.62461) | (1.75782) | (6.64454) | |
0.21087* | 0.15352* | 0.86467* | |
(0.18958) | (0.09604) | (0.51111) | |
−0.07964** | −0.02971* | −1.70526* | |
(0.04148) | (0.01692) | (0.98348) | |
0.03678* | 0.02116 | 1.35241* | |
(0.07482) | (0.02666) | (0.82092) | |
0.026953 | −0.02350 | 3.13714 | |
(0.16569) | (0.06366) | (1.66128) | |
Const. | −16.25145 | 16.90367** | 9.97017 |
(1.62246) | (1.98745) | (2.74611) | |
N. Obs. | 370 | 175 | 195 |
AR1 | −7.69 | −4.39 | −0.73 |
(0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | |
AR2 | 0.10 | 0.87 | −0.65 |
(0.921) | (0.384) | (0.513) | |
Sargan | 43.53 | 188.33 | 42.31 |
(0.182) | (0.161) | (0.217) |
Note(s): The values in parentheses are the results of standard errors, and * is the significance level of the variable being 10: *, 5: **, 1%: ***. In the section referring to tests, the values in parentheses are the p-values of the calculated statistics
Source(s): Prepared by the authors, 2023
Unit root test with variables in level
Variable | Levin, Lin, and Chu (LLC) test | Harris-Tzavalis test (HT) | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Statistic | p-value | Statistic | p-value | |
−17.7524 | 0.0000 | 0.3961 | 0.0000 | |
−6.8504 | 0.0000 | 0.3693 | 0.0000 | |
−1.9e+03 | 0.8856 | 0.4875 | 0.0000 | |
−24.4210 | 1.0000 | 0.2801 | 0.0000 | |
−6.2212 | 0.0000 | 0.3529 | 0.0000 | |
−21.3704 | 1.0000 | 0.2875 | 0.0000 | |
−20.4355 | 1.0000 | 0.3070 | 0.0000 | |
−11.0158 | 0.0000 | 0.7620 | 0.0000 | |
−9.0604 | 0.0000 | 0.9853 | 1.0000 | |
−1.6283 | 0.0517 | 0.8869 | 0.9892 | |
−3.7221 | 0.0001 | 0.1928 | 0.0000 | |
−6.5220 | 0.0000 | 0.3445 | 0.0000 |
Note(s): In both tests, the hypotheses are:
Source(s): Prepared by the authors, 2023
Unit root test with variables after logarithmic transformation
Variable | Levin, Lin and Chu (LLC) test | Harris-Tzavalis (HT) test | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Statistic | p-value | Statistic | p-value | |
−12.2223 | 0.0000 | 0.4165 | 0.0000 | |
−3.63268 | 0.0000 | 0.2651 | 0.0000 | |
−1.5e+07 | 0.0000 | 0.1965 | 0.0000 | |
−7.8e+02 | 0.0523 | 0.2997 | 0.0000 | |
−97.3078 | 0.0000 | 0.3386 | 0.0000 | |
−15.9976 | 0.0015 | 0.1682 | 0.0000 | |
−6.9e+06 | 0.0000 | 0.1840 | 0.0000 | |
−50.3290 | 0.0000 | 0.3353 | 0.0000 | |
−22.2865 | 0.0000 | 0.9771 | 0.0000 | |
−1.2e+02 | 0.0000 | 0.1739 | 0.0000 | |
−91.5620 | 0.0000 | 0.0176 | 0.0000 | |
−8.1089 | 0.0000 | 0.1763 | 0.0000 |
Note(s): In both tests, the hypotheses are:
Source(s): Prepared by the authors, 2023
Note
An example of how institutional quality and financial development can work together to improve economic performance is the USA. The USA has become an economy of incredible institutional and financial strength. The extensive regulatory framework in this country has allowed for large and complex operations in the financial market, which provides the necessary security for the efficient functioning of the markets. In addition, the elevated levels of trust among participants and their trusted legal system have enabled the rapid development of the financial sector. The USA also keeps a resilient financial system, which puts it in a unique position to respond to severe global financial shocks (Acemoglu & Robinson, 2013; Piketty, 2014).
References
Abaidoo, R., & Agyapong, E. K. (2022). Financial development and institutional quality among emerging economies. Journal of Economics and Development, 24(3), 198–216. doi: 10.1108/jed-08-2021-0135.
Abdullah, H., Habibullah, M. S., & Baharumshah, A. Z. (2009). Effects of fiscal policy and institutions on the economic growth of Asian economies: Evidence from dynamic panel data analysis. International Journal of Management Studies, 16(1), 185–212. doi: 10.32890/ijms.16.1.2009.9963.
Acemoglu, D. (2005). Politics and economics exist in weak and strong states, respectively. Journal of Monetary Economics, 52(7), 1199–1226. doi: 10.1016/j.jmoneco.2005.05.001.
Acemoglu, D. (2010). Growth and institutions. In Economic Growth (pp. 107–115). London: Palgrave Macmillan UK.
Acemoglu, D., & Johnson, S. (2005). Unbundling institutions. Journal of Political Economy, 113(5), 949–995. doi: 10.1086/432166.
Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2013). Why nations fail: The origins of power, prosperity, and poverty. Currency.
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review, 91(5), 1369–1401. doi: 10.1257/aer.91.5.1369.
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J.A. (2005). Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth. Handbook of Economic Growth, 1, 385–472.
Acemoglu, D., Aghion, P., & Zilibotti, F. (2006). Distance to frontier, selection, and economic growth. Journal of the European Economic Association, 4(1), 37–74. doi: 10.1162/jeea.2006.4.1.37.
Acemoglu, D., Gallego, F. A., & Robinson, J. A. (2014). Institutions, human capital, and development. Annual Revision Economic, 6(1), 875–912. doi: 10.1146/annurev-economics-080213-041119.
Acharya, V. V. (2009). A theory of systemic risk and design of prudential bank regulation. Journal of Financial Stability, 5(3), 224–255. doi: 10.1016/j.jfs.2009.02.001.
Adeniyi, O. A., Omisakin, O., Egwaikhide, F. O., & Oyinlola, A. (2012). Foreign direct investment, economic growth, and financial sector development in small open developing economies. Economic Analysis and Policy, 42(1), 105–127. doi: 10.1016/s0313-5926(12)50008-1.
Admati, A. R. (2017). A skeptical view of financialized corporate governance. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 31(3), 131–150. doi: 10.1257/jep.31.3.131.
Agénor, P. R. (2003). Benefits and costs of international financial integration: Theory and facts. World Economy, 26(8), 1089–1118. doi: 10.1111/1467-9701.00564.
Aisen, A., & Veiga, F. J. (2013). How does political instability affect economic growth?. European Journal of Political Economy, 29(12), 151–167. doi: 10.5089/9781455211906.001.
Akerlof, G. A. (1978). The market for ‘lemons’: Quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. In Uncertainty in Economics (pp. 235–251). Academic Press.
Alesina, A., Özler, S., Roubini, N., & Swagel, P. (1996). Political instability and economic growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 1(3), 189–211. doi: 10.1007/bf00138862.
Allen, F., Gu, X., & Kowalewski, O. (2018). Financial structure, economic growth and development. In Handbook of finance and development (pp. 31–62). Edward Elgar Publishing.
Alshubiri, F., Jamil, S. A., & Fekir, S. (2023). Corruption control, government effectiveness and banking stability: Does corruption grease or sand the wheels?. Journal of the Knowledge Economy, 1–26. doi: 10.1007/s13132-023-01277-x.
Anderlini, L., Felli, L., Immordino, G., & Riboni, A. (2013). Legal institutions, innovation, and growth. International Economic Review, 54(3), 937–956. doi: 10.1111/iere.12023.
Andrianova, S., Demetriades, P., & Shortland, A. (2008). The government enjoys banks, institutions, and financial development. Journal of Development Economics, 85(1-2), 218–252. doi: 10.1016/j.jdeveco.2006.08.002.
Anwar, S., & Cooray, A. (2012). Financial development, political rights, civil liberties, and economic growth: Evidence from South Asia. Economic Modeling, 29(3), 974–981. doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2012.02.009.
Arcand, J. L., Berkes, E., & Panizza, U. (2015). Too much finance?. Journal of Economic Growth, 20(2), 105–148. doi: 10.1007/s10887-015-9115-2.
Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. The Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 277–297. doi: 10.2307/2297968.
Arellano, M., & Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components models. Journal of Econometrics, 68(1), 29–51. doi: 10.1016/0304-4076(94)01642-d.
Arellano, C., Bai, Y., & Zhang, J. (2012). Firm dynamics and financial development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 59(6), 533–549. doi: 10.1016/j.jmoneco.2012.06.006.
Arestis, P., Demetriades, P. O., & Luintel, K. B. (2001). Financial development and economic growth: The role of stock markets. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 33(1), 16–41. doi: 10.2307/2673870.
Asante, G. N., Takyi, P. O., & Mensah, G. (2023). The impact of financial development on economic growth in sub-Saharan Africa. Does institutional quality matter?. Development Studies Research, 10(1), 2156904. doi: 10.1080/21665095.2022.2156904.
Asiamah, T. A., Steel, W. F., & Ackah, C. (2021). Determinants of credit demand and credit constraints among households in Ghana. Heliyon, 7(10), e08162. doi: 10.1016/j.heliyon.2021.e08162.
Asongu, S. (2014). Finance and democracy in Africa. Institutions and Economies, 6(3), 92–118.
Ball, C. (2009). What is transparency?. Public Integrity, 11(4), 293–308. doi: 10.2753/pin1099-9922110400.
Baltagi, B. H. (2008). Econometric analysis of panel data (Vol. 4, pp. 135–145). Chichester: Wiley.
Baltagi, B. H., Egger, P., & Pfaffermayr, M. (2007). Estimating models of complex FDI: Are there third-country effects?. Journal of Econometrics, 140(1), 260–281. doi: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2006.09.009.
Bandura, W. N., & Dzingirai, C. (2019). Financial development and economic growth in sub-saharan Africa: The role of institutions. PSL Quarterly Review, 72(291), 315.
Barro, R. J. (1984). Rational expectations and macroeconomics in 1984. The American Economic Review, 74(2), 179–182.
Beck, T. (2012). The role of finance in economic development–benefits, risks, and politics In The Oxford Handbook of Capitalism, (Vol. 2011, pp. 161–203). New York: Oxford University Press. doi: 10.1093/oxfordhb/9780195391176.013.0007.
Beck, T. (2020). Finance, institutions and development. In The handbook of institutions and economic development (pp. 218–251). Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.
Beck, T., & Levine, R. (2001). Stock markets, banks, and growth: Correlation or causality?. World Bank Publications.
Beck, T., & Levine, R. (2004). Stock markets, banks, and growth: Panel evidence. Journal of Banking and Finance, 28(3), 423–442. doi: 10.1016/s0378-4266(02)00408-9.
Beck, T., Levine, R., & Loayza, N. (2000). Finance and sources of growth. Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1-2), 261–300. doi: 10.1016/s0304-405x(00)00072-6.
Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & DemirgÜÇ-Kunt, A. (2001). Law, politics, and finance. SSRN 269118, Policy Research Working Papers. doi: 10.1596/1813-9450-2585.
Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Levine, R. (2003). Law and finance: Why does legal origin matter?. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(4), 653–675. doi: 10.1016/j.jce.2003.08.001.
Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Levine, R. (2004). Finance, inequality, and poverty: Cross-country evidence. National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER Working Paper No. 10979. doi: 10.1596/1813-9450-3338.
Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., Laeven, L., & Maksimovic, V. (2006). The determinants of financing obstacles. Journal of International Money and Finance, 25(6), 932–952. doi: 10.1016/j.jimonfin.2006.07.005.
Bekaert, G., Harvey, C., & Lundblad, C. (2005). Does financial liberalization spur growth?. Journal of Financial Economics, 77(1), 3–55. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2004.05.007.
Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115–143. doi: 10.1016/s0304-4076(98)00009-8.
Bodie, Z., & Merton, R. C. (1998). A conceptual framework for analyzing the financial environment. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press.
Boyd, J. H., & De Nicolo, G. (2005). The theory of bank risk taking and competition revisited. The Journal of Finance, 60(3), 1329–1343. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2005.00763.x.
Carletti, E., & Leonello, A. (2019). Credit market competition and liquidity crises. Review of Finance, 23(5), 855–892. doi: 10.1093/rof/rfy026.
Cecchetti, S. G., & Kharroubi, E. (2015). Why does financial sector growth crowd out real economic growth?. BIS Working Papers, no. 490, Bank for International Settlements.
Chang, H.-J. (2011). Institutions and economic development: Theory, policy, and history. Journal of Institutional Economics, 7(4), 473–498. doi: 10.1017/s1744137410000378.
Chen, L., Li, H., Liu, F. H., & Zhou, Y. (2021). Bank regulation and systemic risk: Cross country evidence. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting, 57(1), 353–387. doi: 10.1007/s11156-020-00947-0.
Chinn, M. D., & Ito, H. (2006). What matters for financial development? Capital controls, institutions, and interactions. Journal of Development Economics, 81(1), 163–192. doi: 10.1016/j.jdeveco.2005.05.010.
Claessens, S., & Van Horen, N. (2012). Foreign banks: Trends, impact, and financial stability. International Monetary Fund, London.
Cline, W. R. (2010). Financial globalization, economic growth, and the crisis of 2007-2009. Peterson Institute, NY.
Coase, R. H. (1990). Accounting and the theory of the firm. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 12(1-3), 3–13. doi: 10.1016/0165-4101(90)90038-6.
Coase, R. H. (2012). The firm, the market, and the law. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.
Cooray, A., & Schneider, F. (2018). Does corruption throw sand into or grease the wheels of financial sector development?. Public Choice, 177(1-2), 111–133. doi: 10.1007/s11127-018-0592-7.
Coşkun, Y. (2016). Türkiye konut piyasasında talep eğilimleri ve bilgi bakışımsızlığına yönelik politika önerileri. Bankacılar Dergisi, 96, 122–143.
Cull, R., & Xu, L. C. (2005). Institutions, ownership, and finance: The determinants of profit reinvestment among Chinese firms. Journal of Financial Economics, 77(1), 117–146. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2004.05.010.
Daniel, K. (2017). Thinking, fast and slow. Disponível em. Available from: http://dspace.vnbrims.org:13000/jspui/bitstream/123456789/2224/1/Daniel-Kahneman-Thinking-Fast-and-Slow-.pdf (accessed 15 April 2024).
De Gregorio, J., & Guidotti, P. (1995). Economic growth, convergence clubs, and the role of financial development. World Development, 23(3), 433–448. doi: 10.1016/0305-750x(94)00132-i.
De Haas, R., & Van Lelyveld, I. (2006). Foreign banks and credit stability in central and Eastern Europe: A panel data analysis. Journal of Banking and Finance, 30(7), 1927–1952. doi: 10.1016/j.jbankfin.2005.07.007.
Demetriades, P., & Law, S. H. (2006). Finance, institutions and economic development. International Journal of Finance and Economics, 11(3), 245–260. doi: 10.1002/ijfe.296.
Demirgüç-Kunt, A. (2012). Finance and economic development: The role of government. In A. N. Berger, P. Molyneux, & J. O. S. Wilson (Eds), The Oxford Handbook of Banking (2012) (online ed.). Oxford Academic, 18 Sept. 2012. Available from: https://org/10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199640935.013.0029 (accessed 15 April 2024).
Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Huizinga, H. (2010). Bank activity and funding strategies: The impact on risk and returns. Journal of Financial Economics, 98(3), 626–650. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.06.004.
Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Levine, R. (1996). Stock markets, corporate finance, and economic growth: An overview. The World Bank Economic Review, 10(2), 223–239. doi: 10.1093/wber/10.2.223.
Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Levine, R. (2001). Financial structure and economic growth: A cross-country comparison of banks, markets, and development. (Ed). MIT Press, New York.
Didier, T., Levine, R., Llovet Montanes, R., & Schmukler, S. L. (2021). Capital market financing and firm growth. Journal of International Money and Finance, 118, 102459. doi: 10.1016/j.jimonfin.2021.102459.
Erol, C., Seven, Ü., Aydoğan, B., & Tunc, S. (2013). The impact of financial restructuring after 2001 Turkey crisis on the risk determinants of Turkish commercial bank stocks. International Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7(4).
Ewert, R. & Wagenhofer, A. (2011). Earnings quality metrics and what they measure. SSRN 1697042.
Fabozzi, F., Modigliani, F., & Jones, F. (2014). Foundations financial markets and institutions. NY: Pearson.
Faggian, A., et al. (2019). Human capital and regional development. In Handbook of regional growth and development theories (pp. 149–171).
Fernández-Torres, Y., Gutiérrez-Fernández, M., & Ramajo-Hernández, J. (2018). Business regulation and economic growth: The indirect effect of corruption in Latin America and the Caribbean. Journal of Developmental Entrepreneurship, 23(01), 1850003. doi: 10.1142/s1084946718500036.
Ferran, E. (2012). The regulatory aftermath of the global financial crisis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Fraser Institute (2023). Economic freedom ranking. Available from: https://www.fraserinstitute.org/economic-freedom/dataset?geozone=world&page=dataset&min-year=2&max-year=0&filter=0&year=2017 (accessed 20 June 2023).
Fufa, T., & Kim, J. (2018). Stock markets, banks, and economic growth: Evidence from more homogeneous panels. Research in International Business and Finance, 44, 504–517. doi: 10.1016/j.ribaf.2017.07.120.
Girma, S., & Shortland, A. (2007). The political economy of financial development. Oxford Economic Papers, 60(4), 567–596. doi: 10.1093/oep/gpm040.
Glaeser, E., Johnson, S., & Shleifer, A. (2001). Coase versus the Coasians. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(3), 853–899. doi: 10.1162/00335530152466250.
Glaeser, E. L., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2004). Institutions drive growth?. Journal of Economic Growth, 9(3), 271–303. doi: 10.1023/b:joeg.0000038933.16398.ed.
Goldsmith, R. W. (1969). Financial structure and development. New York, NY: Yale University Press.
Greenwood, J., & Jovanovic, B. (1990). Financial development, growth, and income distribution. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), 1076–1107. doi: 10.1086/261720.
Gurley, J. G., & Shaw, E. S. (1955). Financial aspects of economic development. The American Economic Review, 45(4), 515–538.
Hoeffler, A. (2002). The augmented Solow model and the African growth debate. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 64(2), 135–158. doi: 10.1111/1468-0084.00016.
Holtz-Eakin, D., Newey, W., & Rosen, H. S. (1988). Estimating vector autoregressions with panel data. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 56(6), 1371–1395. doi: 10.2307/1913103.
Huang, H., & Xu, C. (1999). Institutions, innovations, and growth. American Economic Review, 89(2), 438–443. doi: 10.1257/aer.89.2.438.
Janvry, A., & Sadoulet, E. (2020). Using agriculture for development: Supply-and demand-side approaches. World Development, 133, 105003. doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2020.105003.
Jensen, M. C. (1993). The modern industrial revolution, exit, and the failure of internal control systems. The Journal of Finance, 48(3), 831–880. doi: 10.2307/2329018.
Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (2019). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. In Corporate governance (pp. 77–132). Gower.
Julius Otusanya, O. (2011). Corruption as an obstacle to development in developing countries: A review of literature. Journal of Money Laundering Control, 14(4), 387–422. doi: 10.1108/13685201111173857.
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (2013). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. In Handbook of the fundamentals of financial decision making: Part I (pp. 99–127).
Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2011). The worldwide governance indicators: Methodology and analytical issues1. Hague Journal on the Rule of Law, 3(2), 220–246. doi: 10.1017/s1876404511200046.
Khan, S., Peng, Z., & Li, Y. (2019). Energy consumption, environmental degradation, economic growth and financial development in globe: Dynamic simultaneous equations panel analysis. Energy Reports, 5, 1089–1102.
Kim, C. K. (2014). Anti-corruption initiatives and e-government: A cross-national study. Public Organization Review, 14(3), 385–396. doi: 10.1007/s11115-013-0223-1.
King, R. G., & Levine, R. (1993). Finance and growth: Schumpeter might be right. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(3), 717–737. doi: 10.2307/2118406.
Klapper, L., Laeven, L., & Rajan, R. (2006). Entry regulation as a barrier to entrepreneurship. Journal of Financial Economics, 82(3), 591–629. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2005.09.006.
Knack, S., & Keefer, P. (1995). Institutions and economic performance: Cross-country tests using alternative institutional measures. Economics and Politics, 7(3), 207–227. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0343.1995.tb00111.x.
Konadu-Agyemang, K. (2018). IMF and World Bank sponsored structural adjustment programs in Africa: Ghana's experience, 1983-1999. London: Routledge.
Korkmaz, S. (2015). Impact of bank credit on economic growth and inflation. Journal of Applied Finance and Banking, 5(1), 51.
Kose, M. A., Prasad, E., Rogoff, K., & Wei, S.J. (2010). Financial globalization and economic policies. In Handbook of Development Economics (pp. 4283–4359). Elsevier.
La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1997). Legal determinants of external finance. The Journal of Finance, 52(3), 1131–1150. doi: 10.2307/2329518.
La Porta, R., Lopez‐de‐Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1998). Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy, 106(6), 1113–1155. doi: 10.1086/250042.
La Porta, R., Lopez‐de‐Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1999). The quality of government. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 15(1), 222–279. doi: 10.1093/jleo/15.1.222.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (2000). Investor protection and corporate governance. Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1-2), 3–27. doi: 10.1016/s0304-405x(00)00065-9.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F. and Shleifer, A. (2013). Law and finance after a decade of research. In Handbook of the Economics of Finance (pp. 425–491). Elsevier.
Laeven, L., & Valencia, F. (2020). Systemic banking crisis database II. IMF Economic Review, 68(2), 307–361. doi: 10.1057/s41308-020-00107-3.
Levine, R. (1997). Financial development and economic growth: Views and agenda. Journal of Economic Literature, 35(2), 688–726.
Levine, R. (1999). Law, finance, and economic growth. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 8(1-2), 8–35. doi: 10.1006/jfin.1998.0255.
Levine, R. (2005). Finance and growth: Theory and evidence. In Handbook of Economic Growth (Vol. 1, pp. 865–934).
Levine, R., & Zervos, S. (1998). Stock markets, banks, and economic growth. American Economic Review, 537–558.
Levin, A., Lin, C. F., & Chu, C. (2002). Unit root test in panel data: Asymptotic and finite sample properties. Journal of Econometrics, 108, 1–24. doi: 10.1016/s0304-4076(01)00098-7.
Love, I., & Zicchino, L. (2006). Financial development and dynamic investment behavior: Evidence from panel VAR. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 46(2), 190–210. doi: 10.1016/j.qref.2005.11.007.
Lucas, R. E. (1980). Methods and problems in business cycle theory. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 12(4), 696–715. doi: 10.2307/1992030.
Luintel, K. B., Khan, M., Arestis, P., & Theodoridis, K. (2008). Financial structure and economic growth. Journal of Development Economics, 86(1), 181–200. doi: 10.1016/j.jdeveco.2007.11.006.
Masoud, N., & Hardaker, G. (2012). The impact of financial development on economic growth: Empirical analysis of emerging market countries. Studies in Economics and Finance, 29(3), 148–173. doi: 10.1108/10867371211246830.
Mazzucato, M., & Wray, L. R. (2015). Financing the capital development of the economy: A keynes-Schumpeter-Minsky synthesis. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College Working Paper, 837.
Mensah, G., Kofi Osei-Fosu, A., & Nkansah Asante, G. (2023). The effects of public sector management and institutions on stock market development in sub-Saharan Africa. Cogent Economics and Finance, 10(1), 2109278. doi: 10.1080/23322039.2022.2109278.
Miller, M. H. (1977). Debt and taxes. The Journal of Finance, 32(2), 261–275. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1977.tb03267.x.
Minniti, M. (2008). The role of government policy on entrepreneurial activity: Productive, unproductive, or destructive?. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 32(5), 779–790. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6520.2008.00255.x.
Mishkin, F. S. (1999). Financial consolidation: Dangers and opportunities. Journal of Banking and Finance, 23(2-4), 675–691. doi: 10.1016/s0378-4266(98)00084-3.
Modigliani, F., & Perotti, E. (1997). Protection of minority interest and the development of security markets. Managerial and Decision Economics, 18(7‐8), 519–528. doi: 10.1002/(sici)1099-1468(199711/12)18:7/8<519::aid-mde857>3.3.co;2-d.
Muth, J. F. (1961). Rational expectations and the theory of price movements. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 29(3), 315–335. doi: 10.2307/1909635.
Myers, S. C. (1977). Interactions of corporate financing and investment decisions--implications for capital budgeting: Reply. The Journal of Finance, 32(1), 218–220. doi: 10.2307/2326920.
Nguyen, Q. H. (2019). Growth model with financial deepening and productivity heterogeneity. The Japanese Economic Review, 70(1), 123–140. doi: 10.1111/jere.12180.
North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. London: Cambridge University Press.
Panizza, U., & Presbitero, A. F. (2013). Public debt and economic growth in advanced economies: A survey. Swiss Journal of Economics and Statistics, 149(2), 175–204. doi: 10.1007/bf03399388.
Patrick, H. T. (1966). Financial development and economic growth in underdeveloped countries. Economic. Development and Cultural Change, 14(2), 174–189. doi: 10.1086/450153.
Pecé, A. M., Simona, O. E. O., & Salisteanu, F. (2015). Innovation and economic growth: An empirical analysis for CEE countries. Procedia Economics and Finance, 26, 461–467. doi: 10.1016/s2212-5671(15)00874-6.
Pellegrini, L., & Gerlagh, R. (2004). Corruption's effect on growth and its transmission channels. Kyklos, 57(3), 429–456. doi: 10.1111/j.0023-5962.2004.00261.x.
Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the twenty-first century. New Delhi: Harvard University Press.
Przeworski, A., & Vreeland, J. R. (2000). The effect of IMF programs on economic growth. Journal of Development Economics, 62(2), 385–421. doi: 10.1016/s0304-3878(00)00090-0.
Putnam, R. D., et al. (1993). Making democracy work: Civic traditions in modern Italy. New York: Princeton University Press.
Rajan, R. G., & Zingales, L. (2003). The great reversals: The politics of financial development in the twentieth century. Journal of Financial Economics, 69(1), 5–50. doi: 10.1016/s0304-405x(03)00125-9.
Rani, R., & Kumar, N. (2019). On the causal dynamics between economic growth, trade openness and gross capital formation: Evidence from BRICS countries. Global Business Review, 20(3), 795–812. doi: 10.1177/0972150919837079.
Rau, R., Wardrop, R. and Zingales, L. (eds). (2021). The Palgrave handbook of technological finance. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Raza, S. A., Shah, N., & Ali, M. (2019). Acceptance of mobile banking in Islamic banks: Evidence from modified UTAUT model. Journal of Islamic Marketing, 10(1), 357–376. doi: 10.1108/JIMA-04-2017-0038.
Richard, H., et al. (2022). Nudge: Improving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness. London: Penguin Books.
Rioja, F., & Valev, N. (2004). Finance and sources of growth at various stages of economic development. Economic Inquiry, 42(1), 127–140. doi: 10.1093/ei/cbh049.
Roe, M. & Siegel, J. (2008). Political instability's impact on financial development. Harvard Law and Economics Discussion Paper (570).
Roubini, N., & Sala-I-Martin, X. (1992). Financial repression and economic growth. Journal of Development Economics, 39(1), 5–30. doi: 10.1016/0304-3878(92)90055-e.
Roychowdhury, S., Shroff, N., & Verdi, R. S. (2019). The effects of financial reporting and disclosure on corporate investment: A review. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 68(2-3), 101246. doi: 10.1016/j.jacceco.2019.101246.
Sahay, R., Cihak, M., N'Diaye, M. P. M., Barajas, M. A., Pena, M. D. B. A., Bi, R., Gao, M., Kyobe, M. A. J., Nguyen, L., Saborowski, C., & Svirydzenka, K. (2015). Rethinking financial deepening: Stability and growth in emerging markets. Journal of Institutional Economics, 17(33), 73–107.
Sghaier, I. M., & Abida, Z. (2013). Foreign direct investment, financial development, and economic growth: Empirical evidence from North African countries. Journal of International and Global Economic Studies, 6(1), 1–13.
Smit, A. J. (2010). The competitive advantage of nations: Is Porter's Diamond Framework a new theory that explains the international competitiveness of countries?. Southern African Business Review, 14(1).
Song, C. Q., Chang, C. P., & Gong, Q. (2021). Economic growth, corruption, and financial development: Global evidence. Economic Modeling, 94, 822–830. doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2020.02.022.
Stepanyan, V., & Guo, K. (2011). Determinants of bank credit in emerging market economies. NY: International Monetary Fund.
Stiglitz, J. E. (1985). Information and economic analysis: A perspective. The Economic Journal, 95, 21–41. doi: 10.2307/2232867.
Stock, J. H., & Watson, M. W. (2020). Introduction to econometrics. NY: Pearson.
Su, D., Xu, S., & Tong, Z. (2023). Credit availability and corporate risk-taking: Evidence from China's green credit policy. Post-communist Economies, 35(3), 236–270. doi: 10.1080/14631377.2023.2169516.
Taiwo, J. N., & Falohun, T.O. (2016). SME financing and its effects on Nigerian economic growth. European Journal of Business, 4(4).
Thiel, M. (2001). Finance and economic growth-a review of theory and the available evidence. European Economy-Economic Papers, 2008-2015, (158).
Tuncay, M. (2018). Do political risks matter in financial markets?: Evidence from Turkey. Eurasian Business Review, 8(2), 209–227. doi: 10.1007/s40821-017-0077-5.
Valickova, P., Havranek, T., & Horvath, R. (2015). Financial development and economic growth: A meta‐analysis. Journal of Economic Surveys, 29(3), 506–526. doi: 10.1111/joes.12068.
Van den Berg, H. (2016). Economic growth and development. NJ: World Scientific Publishing Company.
Williamson, S. D. (1987). Costly monitoring, loan contracts, and equilibrium credit rationing. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102(1), 135–145. doi: 10.2307/1884684.
World Bank (2023). Worldwide governance indicators (GI). Available from: https://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/ (accessed 20 June 2023).
Yang, B. (2011). Does democracy foster financial development? An empirical analysis. Economics Letters, 112(3), 262–265. doi: 10.1016/j.econlet.2011.05.012.
Yang, F. (2019). The impact of financial development on economic growth in middle-income countries. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, 59, 74–89. doi: 10.1016/j.intfin.2018.11.008.
Zhou, Q., Bao, Y., Zhao, Y., He, X., Cui, C., & Liu, Y. (2022). Impacts of government credit on government performance of public‒private partnership project in China: A WSR system theory perspective. Sustainability, 14(11), 6886. doi: 10.3390/su14116886.
Further reading
Fabozzi, F. J., et al. (1977). Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics, 5(2), 147–175. doi: 10.1016/0304-405x(77)90015-0.
Harris, R. D., & Tzavalis, E. (1999). Inference for unit roots in dynamic panels where the time dimension is fixed. Journal of Econometrics, 91(2), 201–226. doi: 10.1016/s0304-4076(98)00076-1.
Raza, S. A., Shah, N., & Arif, I. (2021). Relationship between FDI and economic growth in the presence of a good governance system: Evidence from OECD Countries. Global Business Review, 22(6), 1471–1489. doi: 10.1177/0972150919833484.
World Development Indicators (2023). Available from: https://datatopics.worldbank.org/world-development-indicators/about-world-development-indicators.html (accessed 27 June 2023).