“Win-lose” globalization and the weaponization of economic policies by nation-states

Sergio Mariotti (Department of Management, Economics and Industrial Engineering, Politecnico di Milano, Milan, Italy)

Critical Perspectives on International Business

ISSN: 1742-2043

Article publication date: 16 July 2024

Issue publication date: 18 October 2024

6146

Abstract

Purpose

After decades of hypergrowth, since the 2008 global financial crisis there has been a deceleration of globalization and a partial jamming of its main engines (trade and foreign direct investment [FDI]). This study aims to critically reflect on the current phase, labeling it as “win-lose globalization” characterized by firm-firm competition increasingly intertwined with that between the respective nation-states, which aim to be the relative winners, even at the expense of joint absolute gains. Acting as “strategists,” states implement policies to weaponize economic interdependences, which the paper analyzes.

Design/methodology/approach

The approach is “problem setting” rather than “problem solving.” The latter offers well-defined solutions but often assumes unambiguous definitions of problems, which obscure their complexity. This phase is so intricate that the problem itself is problematic. Thus, to advance knowledge, the focus is given on nation-state policies: FDI screening and the politicization of international trade relations; protectionism; misuses of antitrust and regulation.

Findings

The intensification of firm-firm/state-state competition, seeking disproportionate gains over rivals, is the ultimate result of the contradictions and dissatisfactions accumulated over decades of globalization, the benefits of which have been far from equally distributed. Conflicts in international economic relations are bound to intensify, and a return to win-win globalization is unlikely. International cooperation to strengthen existing/new supranational governance institutions in the interest of absolute global inclusive benefits is urgently needed.

Originality/value

The paper integrates the international business debate on the fate of globalization with interpretations from industrial policy studies and international relations theory. This allows for suggestions for policymakers, corporate executives and scholars.

Keywords

Citation

Mariotti, S. (2024), "“Win-lose” globalization and the weaponization of economic policies by nation-states", Critical Perspectives on International Business, Vol. 20 No. 5, pp. 638-659. https://doi.org/10.1108/cpoib-09-2023-0089

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2024, Sergio Mariotti.

License

Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial & non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


1. Introduction

For decades, international business (IB) scholars have devoted attention to globalization and how multinational enterprises (MNEs) benefit from it by entering markets through trade and foreign direct investment (FDI). However, events such as the 2008 global financial crisis (GFC), the pandemic and the war in Ukraine, forced a change of course. Studies investigating the slowdown of globalization and proposing adjustments to the MNE strategy have multiplied (e.g. Buckley, 2020, 2023; Petricevic and Teece, 2019). A 2024 editorial published by the Journal of International Business Studies warns that currently «the political dimension of international business dominates the agenda….the optimism in the 1990s on a world without borders has turned into a debate about techno-nationalism, de-globalization, and trade and FDI restrictions» (Beugelsdijk and Luo, 2024, p.1).

In this paper, I propose an interpretation of the current state of globalization as a result of unprecedented development of the world economy, but one that has dragged economic and social negative consequences that have often been improperly sidelined or underestimated by both scholars and policymakers. International markets have become crowded and new and old economic powers compete fiercely to share them out with the support of nation-states. The latter has reemerged powerfully as protagonists in the exercise of their sovereignty and as strategists in orchestrating national policies aimed at international rivalry, often invoking supposedly superior interests of their own peoples.

The weakening of the institutions created in the postwar period for the governance of international relations and conflict resolution is both the result and the cause of this state of affairs. Hereafter, I christen this new normal “win-lose” globalization, meaning that the latter is accompanied by conflict between rival firms intertwined with conflict between rival states, which increases the economic and political distance between winners and losers. In proposing this notion, I build on the critical scholarship of globalization, which has long illuminated the profound political imbalances and social inequalities generated by decades of hyperglobalization (Rodrik, 2008; Stiglitz, 2017; Williamson, 2005), as well as on international relations theory when it underlies the context of anarchy in which the state-state/firm-firm rivalry play out (Havercroft and Prichard, 2017). “Anarchy” is understood as the absence of supranational bodies capable of defending the market economy, promoting coordination among states, enforcing agreements and sanctioning their deviations, and supporting the growth and survival of nations in the light of a progression toward welfare-oriented global equilibria.

Section 2 outlines the new actorness of nation-states in the global context. It is argued that the labels “deglobalization” and “slowbalization” are unsatisfactory for distilling the meaning of ongoing phenomena; accordingly, the notion of win-lose globalization and the changing role of the strategist state are discussed. To do this effectively, it comes in handy to preface some essential data that account for recent global trends (Section 2.1). The following sections present some stylized facts that indicate how government policies have veered in the direction of a headwind against FDI and free trade. Through the notion of weaponization applied to interstate rivalry, these policies are analyzed in three areas: FDI regulatory screening and the politicization of international trade relations; protectionist industrial policies; misuses of antitrust and industry regulation. Then, referring to the long-term forecasts of leading international institutes, it is argued that the most likely scenario is an exacerbation of the causes that led to win-lose globalization. Finally, some implications for both international policy and IB research are proposed.

2. Reshaping globalization and the actorness of the nation-state

2.1 Global trends

Globalization refers to a state of the world involving increasingly thick networks of interdependence at multi-continental distances within a context of transnational and transcultural integration of human and nonhuman activities (Keohane and Nye, 2000). FDI and trade are driving forces behind globalization. Table 1 shows the dynamics of these indicators relative to GDP. Between 1990 and 2007, which marked the peak for FDI flows and the early symptoms of GFC, the compound average annual rate of FDI stood at +11.85%. This rate was more than double that of world GDP and 50% higher than that of trade. Between 2007 and 2014, the FDI rate experienced a significant negative shift (–4.5%), while the rate of trade remained above that of GDP. In the most recent period (2014–2022) the FDI rate turned slightly positive. However, at 1.5%, the rate remains about half that of trade and GDP over the same period.

Figure 1 delves into 1970–2022 FDI flows. Caution should be paid to FDI as a measure of temporal variation in the degree of globalization. The data underestimate the extent of internationalization processes over time because of their primary purpose (they are collected by central banks to construct a country's balance of payments). In fact, when MNEs establish a solid foothold in a country, the likelihood that they will finance locally their further expansion increases (Hennart and Sutherland, 2022). However, Figure 1 offers compelling evidence that at the onset of the 21st century, particularly after 2007, the FDI regime went from an almost exponential growth phase to one of high volatility and uncertain trends.

This “reshaping of globalization” has raised profound issues to IB theory, calling into question the relationships between government policies and the increasing VUCA (volatility–uncertainty–complexity–ambiguity) (Buckley, 2020; Petricevic and Teece, 2019). The literature has assigned different labels to the phenomenon. The term deglobalization suggests the idea of a retreat of globalization, replaced by a process of regionalization (Enderwick and Buckley, 2020), or islandization (Laudicina and Peterson, 2016) through back-shoring and re-shoring, as well as the location of supply chains within geopolitical areas populated by friendly partners with whom to cooperate and share industrial policies (Witt et al., 2023). The term slowbalization (Bakas, 2016) conveys the message of a gradual slowdown, thus failing to explain instability and zigzagging of FDI. Some scholars advance the idea of a “new” vulnerability of globalization under the pressure of geopolitical factors. They agree that neither the forces of globalization nor deglobalization will prevail, but rather an unstable struggle between them will persist (Cui et al., 2023). Indeed, empirics show that although global trade and FDI have slowed in importance as engines of global growth, a reversal has not occurred. In addition to previous studies (Antràs, 2020; Goldberg and Reed, 2023), Figure 2 provides confirmation by disaggregating the two main components of FDI (greenfields versus M&As) over the past decade (2012–2022). Greenfield projects announced over the period, while fluctuating in value, have not declined but rather grown, to outpace M&As in 2022. Greenfields being the expansive component of FDI (M&As being a change of ownership in the international market for corporate control), the most genuine prerogative of globalization – the interconnectedness between areas of the world economy – continues to broaden its base at an ever-increasing pace.

As an alternative to the aforementioned labels, my proposal to adopt the term win-lose globalization emphasizes the progressively conflictual nature of globalization, rather than referring to its current turbulence, which in itself is not very explanatory. To properly introduce the concept a historical overview is appropriate.

2.2 Past and present of globalization

After WWII, the world economy had a prolonged period of substantial growth. Enterprises from Western countries ventured around the globe, facilitated by the shortcomings and ultimate dissolution of the Soviet Union Empire. The demand of business to nation-states was market liberalization, the elimination of protective barriers, and a nonbinding approach that would allow Adam Smith's invisible hand and the Ricardian mechanisms of trade and growth to operate so relatively benefiting all countries (Stiglitz, 2017). This hyperglobalization was glorified by some scholars. Fukuyama (1992) predicted the impending “end of history,” suggesting that liberal democracy and capitalism would spread to all nations. Ohmae (1990) asserted that borders would no longer constrain the world and that MNEs were becoming “place-less” and “stateless” as corporate allegiance shifted from national identity to a unified global mission. Although other scholars pointed out that statelessness was an illusion (Weiss, 1998), these hyperbolas are somewhat revealing of the orthodoxy of that period, which assumed a flat world in which liberal order and increased economic interdependence would promote global development, the spread of democratic values, and peace by increasing the cost of conflict between states (Friedman, 2005).

The implied paradigm is that of win-win globalization: MNEs organize themselves through global value chains (GVCs), combining market- and resource-seeking strategies to maximize profit. At the same time, their global expansion produces far-reaching positive externalities, including the options given to poorer nations to join GVCs to grow, instead of having to invest decades to build themselves up: «this reversal of fortunes constitutes perhaps the most momentous global economic change in the last 100 years» (Baldwin, 2012, p.13).

The win-win thesis was based on evidence that while Western MNEs were making record profits, emerging economies were booming. In particular, the countries experienced greater integration with the world economy grew the fastest. In countries such as China, India, the four Asian tigers, Vietnam and others, exports and FDIs have undoubtedly played an important role in domestic growth and reducing poverty rates. Faced with this, in past decades, most economists and policymakers have adhered to the so-called “globalization consensus,” i.e. the dominant economic narrative assuming that economies with greater liberalization of business and a narrower economic role for the state experience greater economic growth and less inequality (Wade, 2010).

However, things that seem good or unproblematic may not be, and criticism based on established theory but also on open empirical investigation is needed (Alvesson and Deetz, 2020). Critical research on globalization began to highlight its uneven outcomes, with winners and losers across different regions, countries and social groups (Williamson, 2005). Over time skeptics of globalization traced that series of geoeconomic and geopolitical changes that would lead to the recent upheavals (for a review, Dabic et al., 2021). The consensus on win-win globalization evaporates. Development economist Dani Rodrik (2008) decrees its death; Nobel laureate Joseph Stiglitz (2017) explicitly titles one of his articles “The overselling of globalization”, arguing how politicians and some economists overestimated the benefits and underestimated the costs, fueling confidence in the elites who supported globalization.

What has gained new consensus is that strong contradictions and imbalances have accompanied globalization, opening to the deterioration of international economic relations and a season of geopolitical conflicts and wars. Just as a limestone cliff gradually wears away, losing a piece each day carried away by the weather, and collapses with consequent disaster only when along one of the wall’s many joints the force of gravity prevails, so the world economy is overturned as a result of behaviors and policies of economic and institutional actors whose effects accumulate over time. In this narrative, rather than reality, it is the IB mainstream that suddenly changes, bringing new interpretive emphasis to aspects already analyzed in the literature but underestimated. In this regard, the JIBS editorial's admission that the past three decades have «lulled us asleep a little bit» when it comes to recognizing the political dimension of IB is good news for course correction (Beugelsdijk and Luo, 2024, p.4).

As Keohane and Nye (2000) observe, the increased depth of globalism implies “pluralization”, i.e. an increase in the number and variety of agents participating in the global network and governance based on a multiplicity of nation-states. The extension and intensification of interdependencies has led to rivalries among established MNEs and between them and new MNEs in a plurality of both developed and emerging countries. The international diffusion of technical progress resulting from R&D investments by advanced-economy MNEs has caused the exacerbation of inter-firm competition. In addition, new technological paradigms, such as ICT, have been characterized by the so-called four S’s (Haskel and Westlake, 2017): sunk costs-synergies-scalability-spillovers. These factors have accentuated the need for public investment because private firms have simultaneously faced a high level of uncertainty and the difficulty of sustaining large-scale operations and appropriating the full profit potential. In this way, the interaction between MNEs and nation-states has become increasingly dense, in a circular relationship of causality. Moreover, scholars realized that global competition had not only intensified considerably, but that a period of continuous and painful restructuring was opening up (Ruigrok and Van Tulder, 2013). It became apparent that the world was not set on a trajectory bound for supra-national integration driven by unrestricted globalization. The main paradox is that the least developed countries that have most positively benefited from globalization have grown through economic policies that have violated all the rules by which the orthodoxy of free trade and free capital flows would have wanted the game to be played out: failure to adopt private property rights; reluctant, if not absent, privatizations under the egis of state capitalism; protectionism through import quotas, local content requirements, export subsidies; restrictions on capital flows (Rodrik, 2002).

International relations theory offers alternative explanations for this evolution. Liberal institutionalism (Keohane, 1984) identifies the inability of states to cooperate in building interdependence and a supporting global infrastructure as the main reason. Domestic political pressures against globalization have led countries to opt out of economic interdependence. Rodrik (2008, p.1) shares this view by describing the state of anarchy in which international relations take place: «global markets are only “weakly embedded”. There is no global anti-trust authority, no global lender of last resort, no global regulator, no global safety nets, and, of course, no global democracy…global markets suffer from weak governance, and therefore from weak popular legitimacy».

Structural realism (Waltz, 1979) sees the end of single-country hegemony in world governance as the key argument. The exceptionalism observed during the era of US-USSR bipolarity and then US unipolarity made globalizers believe that the world was increasingly ruled by markets. However, «with the end of bipolarity the distribution of capabilities across states has become extremely lopsided. Rather than elevating economic forces and depressing political ones, the inequalities of international politics enhance the political role of one country. Politics, as usual, prevail on economics» (Waltz, 1999, p.700).

The two theories envision different scenarios for the world economy, and further research is needed to investigate their implications (Witt, 2019). However, reality tells us that both the US hegemony has come to an end, mainly due to the rise of China in the global economy, and that nation-states have been unable to promote effective supranational institutions. Looking ahead, it can be said that a future hegemonic stability and a new world order capable of restoring momentum to globalization are far from materializing. Therefore, it is worth delving into the state-state and state-MNE issue to better understand the new globalization paradigm.

2.3 The strategist state and win-lose globalization

Within the IB literature, Lenway and Murtha (1994) and Murtha and Lenway (1994) laid the groundwork for addressing state-MNE relations. Moving beyond the state as a provider of public goods and other externalities, they advance the concept of the state as strategist, i.e. a state deliberately oriented to make strategic choices and implement policies that can affect the international strategies of firms. The authors argue that national institutional arrangements contribute differently to the state's capabilities to do so. A taxonomy is proposed, distinguishing between pluralist (e.g. the US, most European countries, India), corporatist (e.g. West Germany, Japan, East Asia), command (e.g. China), and transitional (e.g. Eastern and Central Europe) countries.

As regard as pluralist and transitional countries, they conclude: «governments often target MNCs with inducements that appeal to competitive self-interest. MNCs will always accept inducements, provided governments' proposals fit within ranges of activities that the firms would pursue on their own, given their corporate strategies», further, «MNCs will not enter into processes of mutual strategic adaptation with governments unless they have assurances that the governments can and will pursue consistent policies over time», and finally, «governments and MNCs can achieve more». But «[p]ublic officials should recognize that industrial strategies have the highest probabilities of success when they maximize the scope for market mechanisms to select winners and losers» (Murtha and Lenway, 1994, p.127). This description is close to Cerny’s (1997) concept of the “competition state”, pursuing marketization, liberalization of cross-border movements, and privatization of public services, consistent with an orthodox model of economic liberalism. It expresses the dominant paradigm of firm-state relationship at that time in most countries of the industrialized West: firms expanding into international markets do not want a weak state, but a gendarme of the “free market economy” in the general interest of businesses, one that does not interfere with the strategic decisions they make on their own. And there was no need for global political entities to guide and safeguard the internationalization processes (Rodrik, 2017).

For command and corporatist countries, they analyze the state-firm coordination mechanisms designed and deployed to orchestrate internationalization processes with varying degrees of dirigisme and state capitalism. Among these, the experience of developmental countries is examined for their prevailing orientation to push domestic firms toward global strategies that centralize most value chain activities in their home countries and treat the world as a unified market that can be served through exports, i.e. an inward-looking strategy aimed at maximizing endogenous growth, as opposed to the outward-looking strategy of pluralistic countries.

Building on this conceptual framework, what can be said about the current role of the strategist state? Throughout the world, the economic and social imbalances of globalization have legitimized states to develop an interventionist vocation, forcefully reassert their national sovereignty and implement policies to expand/defend the living space of their enterprises. Governments have become highly proactive in supporting the creation of home-based MNEs as a vehicle to promote domestic growth for the benefit of the population and social coalitions. Success in inter-firm competition depends largely on the outcomes of inter-state competition, so MNEs are under increasing pressure to align with political agendas, being aware that their internationalization strategies would be less effective if they were not consistent with geopolitical interests. While lobbying political actors for the protection of their interest at home and abroad, MNEs must closely follow political developments and international relations to understand, anticipate, and react to political moves (Meyer and Li, 2022).

Therefore, countries have definitely moved away from the “competition state” paradigm, but also from the “developmental state”. Compared with traditional developmentalism, the current interventionism differs mainly in the following aspects:

  • globalization is no longer seen as a means of improving national economies through international cooperation and externalities, but predominantly as a worldwide extension/intensification of economic interdependencies through which rival strategist states confront each other in a noncooperative game for exclusive advantages;

  • the dominant rationale is national security and limiting the competitiveness of others rather than strengthening one's own, including through an escalation of hostile acts, threats and retaliation;

  • the economic doctrine shifts from a Schumpeterian view in which win-win outcomes are attainable through cross-fertilization and synergistic cooperation to one in which competition among countries is win-loss, and

  • with regard to innovation and productivity, the state fails to recognize the importance of technological interconnectivity and resource complementarity; its strategy fosters domestic innovation to include an antagonistic strategy of weakening rival nations (Luo, 2022; Mariotti, 2022).

As shown in Section 2.1, these dynamics do not disrupt but destabilize trade and FDI. I refer to this phase as "win-lose” globalization to denote the irreducible content of conflict and instability it expresses in generating winners and losers, no longer just between developed countries (and their home-based MNEs) and undeveloped countries, but between old and new players aspiring to a renewed world order armed by their economic policy and their strategic state-firm interactions. The context of anarchy due to the weakening of cooperative international governance exacerbates the competition between rival nation-states.

Win-lose globalization does not necessarily correspond to a zero-sum game: win means absolute or relative gains and lose can also be a positive gain, if significantly less than the other side’s. According to realism, relative gain may hold greater significance than absolute gain because «[w]hen faced with possibility of cooperating for mutual gain, states that feel insecure must ask how the gain will be divided. They are compelled to ask not ‘Will both of us gain?’ but 'Who will gain more?' If an expected gain is to be divided, say, in the ratio of two to one, one state may use its disproportionate gain to implement a policy intended to damage or destroy the other. Even the prospect of large absolute gains for both parties does not elicit their cooperation so long as each fears how the other will use its increased capabilities» (Waltz, 1979, p.105).

Win-lose globalization is not a reworking of “deglobalization.” The latter implies a weakening of interdependencies so that countries rely less on other countries’ goods, services, and investments (Witt et al., 2023), which rationally should lead to an intensification of international relations within friendly geopolitical blocs, but fewer grounds for conflict between blocs. On the contrary, the appellation “win-lose” indicates that while international relations remain dense (as documented in Section 2.1), the decoupling is often “offensive” rather than “defensive” in nature (Ando et al., 2024). It aims more at striking an opponent in strategic competition – e.g. preventing it from gaining access to technologies and products – rather than limiting dependence on strategic rivals in product supply, an issue on which the current debate on reshoring and friend-shoring is predominantly focused.

This confrontational nature is fraught with consequences. As contradictions intensify, the need to safeguard national interests and security becomes compelling (Helleiner, 2021). Populism gains traction among the people, fueled by the belief that other communities are primarily responsible for the problems. Political parties fan the flame of nationalism by using the globalization of “others” as a scapegoat for their own failures in managing social welfare. The emergence of state interventionist policies marks a quantum leap in the geopolitics of conflict, which now the Russia-Ukraine brings closer to Western industrialized countries, with the potential to further destabilize globalization (Goldberg and Reed, 2023).

Below, after briefly highlighting how in win-lose globalization the attitude of governments toward internationalization has changed, I will show what targeted policies nation-states exploit to shape the scope, quality and direction of globalization in accordance with their international policy.

3. The political weapons in the arsenal of the nation-state

3.1 Headwinds for foreign direct investment and trade

The extent to which governments' attitudes toward FDI have changed is evident from UNCTAD data. Between 2000 and 2022, FDI restriction/regulation measures increased from 6% to 28% of the total, approaching the share of liberalization/promotion measures (42% versus 58%) in the year 2021, in relation to the COVID pandemic (Figure 3). The share of restrictive measures is expected to increase due to the Russian-Ukrainian war and sanctions implemented by several countries, which include restrictions or bans on FDI to and from the Russian Federation and Belarus, as well as counter-sanctions by the Russian Federation. The main actors in this policy shift are not the developing countries, in an effort to protect their infant industry and promote the development of their economies. About two-thirds of the measures taken in these countries are aimed at liberalizing, promoting, or facilitating FDI. In contrast, the vast majority of measures (about 80%) taken in developed countries have introduced new restrictions and regulations or strengthened existing ones.

Evenett and Fritz (2022) in their report based on the GTA database confirm the pervasiveness of the protectionist trend, which involves trade and other sensitive activities. Summarizing all measures implemented by G20 countries to liberalize markets or harm foreign interests through barriers, restrictions and free market distortions, the report shows that in 2022 there were only 5,800 interventions aimed at market liberalization compared to 30,125 that harmed foreign interests. Significantly, the percentage of G20 countries' exports at risk due to foreign discrimination policy doubled between 2009 and 2022, from 40% to over 80%. Most discriminatory interventions came from the US (25%), China (20%) and the three largest EU countries (France, Germany and Italy, 19%). Together, they account for nearly two-thirds of the overall total. In contrast, these five countries collect only slightly more than a third of the total liberalization measures, with very modest shares for the US (7%) and China (9%). Protectionism has epicenter in major countries, but it spreads worldwide. Nearly 75% of global goods exports today face trade distortions, compared to less than 40% before the GFC.

In regards to the recovery of protectionist sovereignty of nation-states, the next sections describe the main policies that serve as the building blocks of their strategy: FDI regulatory screening and politicization of international economic relations; protectionist industrial policy (re-shoring and friend-shoring, techno-nationalism, protection/support for national champions and state-owned enterprises); misuses of antitrust and industry regulations. All the policies discussed below can be ascribed the label of “nothing new”, as each of them can be traced back to some country and period in the past. What is new is the pervasiveness and intensity of the implementation of these policies, which foreshadow a systematic and unison change in the strategic behavior of states in the domestic and global context. I associate this change with the weaponization of industrial policy, as a metaphor for the over-politicization by nation-states of programs and measures that had been neutral and peaceful, in order to inflict harm and gain lasting advantages over other nation-states (see Galeotti, 2022, and Mattson, 2020 on the origins and evolution of the metaphor, now used in reference to so many aspects of social life, ranging from information, finance, migration, GVCs, energy, medicine, etc.).

3.2 Foreign direct investment regulatory screening and the politicization of international trade relations

According to UNCTAD (2023), since 1995 at least 37 countries have introduced a regulatory framework for screening FDI and eight more countries are set to do so in the near future. The adoption or revision of screening mechanisms has particularly increased since the second half of the 2000s onwards, after the GFC. Developed economies were early adopters, with 16 G20 countries implementing such measure.

A notable example is the Committee on Foreign Investment in the US (CFIUS). Established in 1975, CFIUS was originally designed to collect information on inward FDI. However, through legislative reforms it has become an effective regulatory agency (Lee and Maher, 2022). The American media has called CFIUS the main weapon in the Trump Administration's protectionist arsenal. The Biden Administration continued down this path by further intensifying pressure on the Committee and introduced a new screening regime that aims to ensure that incoming firms cannot engage in activities that support China’s or other countries’ malicious intentions, especially in high-tech sectors.

In general, the introduction of FDI screening has been dictated by national security concerns. However, the definition of “national security” has expanded to encompass the vague categories of “critical know-how,” “strategic assets” and activities involving access to sensitive personal information or the potential to influence public opinion. The measures reveal a common trend throughout the world (Napolitano, 2019): broadening the sectors in which investments are subject to scrutiny for national security reasons and require government authorization; reducing the FDI thresholds that trigger notification requirements; enlarging the list of protected public interests; extending administrative investigation deadlines; and strengthening special prescription and inhibition power of public authorities.

By expanding the use and scope of FDI screening, politics is threatening the delicate balance between security concerns and attracting FDI for national growth. Ambiguity and obscurity have become common features of FDI policies, granting countries substantial discretion to invoke national security as a reason for blocking investments. This has intentionally opened up for possible abuses of regulatory control and provided room for politicians and economic agents to secure FDI to support their political and business agendas (Lai, 2021).

A further consequence concerns the effects on screening targets. The case in point is China, the main target of Western countries. Screening has affected the decrease in its cross-border M&As, but it has pushed the country to intensify greenfield projects: in the 2010–2017 period, the ratio in value between M&As and greenfield projects averaged 1.8; in the 2018–2023 period, the ratio reversed in favor of greenfield projects, whose value became 1.6 times that of M&As. Even, in the last three years, greenfields have outperformed M&As by as much as 2.7 times. In addition, in 2023 Chinese companies broke all previous records for outward greenfields, with 90% of them planned in developing countries, particularly in North Africa and Southeast Asia (fDi Markets database and Dettoni, 2024). China's expansionism confirms the ungovernable logic of win-lose globalization, which triggers countermoves to extend global interdependencies along shifting geographic directions.

Finally, recent initiatives have extended screening to outward FDI to prevent foreign transfers of resources and technologies, vital to national security and international leadership, from benefiting countries with hostile intentions toward the nation. In the US, a proposal has been put forward, endorsed both Congress and the White House, for a new FDI review regime for US companies–the “reverse CFIUS”–on the premise that it is no longer enough to secure a “relative” advantage over competitors, but one must maintain “as large of a lead as possible” (according to the remarks by National Security Advisor Jake Sullivan). The EU is also poised to follow suit, as the European Commission has included in its 2023 Work Program a review of the EU's FDI screening legislation concerning the introduction of controls on outward strategic investments.

Not dissimilar is what has long been happening to international trade. Since the early 2000s, in an escalation of geopolitical conflicts, the unilateral actions of various nation-states, including the US and European countries, have challenged the multilateral institutions that promoted postwar economic balances. Appealing to “Security Exception Articles” invocations of national security defense have proliferated in recent years, overriding a growing number of WTO obligations in support of free trade, even though national security should only serve as an exception (Boklan and Bahri, 2020). The WTO is now in danger of losing legitimacy because its dispute settlement system has been hampered, mainly due to the US attack on its rules and regulations during the Trump Administration (with no rectification by President Biden) and the subsequent shift toward unilateralism and economic nationalism by other member countries. Divisions over governance and conditionality have undermined the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank, while China has sought to promote its own global institutions, such as the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank.

These improper procedures are indicative of a trend toward the “politicization” of international economic relations, i.e. a move away from the multilateral system that prevailed for over half a century, characterized by neutrality in the interests of international cooperation, nondiscrimination, deregulation/liberalization, and fair competition. The limited indications emerging from some initiatives to reform these international institutions are not enough to look optimistically to the future. Scholars and policymakers scramble to propose solutions, but no consensus has been reached on how to respond to the decline of the multilateral economic order (Sacerdoti and Borlini, 2023).

3.3. A renewed mission-oriented industrial policy

In the 1970s and 1980s, Japan was the paradigm of an industrial policy that effectively combined mission- and diffusion-oriented approaches to maximize the developmental state's efforts at technological catch-up and strategic protectionism of domestic industry in key sectors of the economy. The pivotal role was played by MITI (Ministry of International Trade and Industry), which concerted a national strategy aimed both at: implementing a “sunset” policy, mitigating the process of decline of traditional industries (textiles and shipbuilding); fostering cooperation among domestic firms in precompetitive research to generate knowledge as a public good; capturing a greater share of world markets in selected high-tech sectors. This policy achieved considerable success in those years and was unmatched worldwide (Johnson, 1982).

The US, along with France and the UK, also implemented mission-oriented programs, primarily promoted by the Department of Defense, with mixed results. Products and technologies conceived directly from US mission-oriented programs accounted for a small share of the economy, while the largest component of their overall impact was due to diffusion-oriented policies (Ergas, 1987). The US policy stance has always been against a Japanese-style industrial policy, in the belief that market forces could guarantee comparable or superior outcomes. Consistently, in the late 1980s, the US federal government promoted a transition of its industrial policy toward a diffusion-oriented paradigm because of disillusionment with the logic of mission orientation (Chiang, 1991).

Coming to the present, the US, in deliberate contrast to the tradition, embraces a mission-oriented policy to safeguard domestic industry and counter the threat posed by China. The US now recognizes that a laissez-faire approach to private sector decision-making is untenable when it affects national interests and critical technologies. Indeed, scholars and practitioners agree that the Chips and Science Act represents a shift from traditional market-oriented liberalism to intervention-oriented techno-nationalism, ushering in a new era of zero-sum thinking and geopolitical prioritization (Luo and Van Assche, 2023). In this view, other scholars have theorized the need for a “mission economy”, based on a renewed form of state activism as a prerequisite for addressing the most pressing international challenges (Mazzucato, 2021).

The new US industrial policy goes beyond the Chips and Science Act. In the aftermath of the two previous administrations (Obama’s “Remaking America” and Trump’s “America first” programs), the Biden Administration has remained committed to rebuilding domestic manufacturing capacity. The 2022 Inflation Reduction Act (IRA) represents a significant milestone. The IRA legislative package combines large-scale green subsidies with health savings and new revenue measures. However, it contains protectionist elements that blatantly violate WTO rules. Of particular concern is the introduction of local content requirements and large-scale production subsidies. These measures distort trade and FDI by providing significant incentives for reshoring and encouraging European and Asian firms to relocate factories to the US (Kleimann et al., 2023).

To compete in attracting investment, the EU has responded by implementing the “European Green Deal Industrial Plan” (sometimes referred to as the Buy European Act) and changing European state aid rules to offset IRA subsidies. In addition, discussions are underway on the creation of an EU-wide “Sovereignty Fund” (Kritikos and Pagoulatos, 2023). Notably, the EU has its own “European Chips Act,” which shares a similar mission and legislative framework as its American counterpart (Christen, 2023). Furthermore, the EU has activated initiatives to encourage re-shoring (Amighini et al., 2023).

More generally, Seidl and Schmitz (2023), reconstructing the evolution of EU industrial policy, point out that past attempts to create a dirigiste Europe have always proved a failure. Europe has relied on the creation of supranational markets, especially after the “recasting” of the European arrangement along neoliberal lines in the 1980s. But things are changing, and the authors show how we are witnessing in Europe the first successful push for a market-directing industrial policy, i.e. one aimed at steering markets toward longer-term purposes, under the banner of technological sovereignty and geo-dirigisme.

The rise of Chinese power is a key factor in these changes. What other countries fear in competing with China is not merely short-term competition over market shares, but the long-term emergence of a technology gap in China’s favor, which could be difficult to close and serve as the foundation for future economic and political supremacy. The Chinese desire for leadership in critical technologies was already evident in 2015 with the launch of the “Made in China” plan, at a time when the world was still actively engaged in weaving relations with that country. Then, in the context of the trade war initiated by the Trump Administration, the “Dual Circulation Strategy” was launched with two main objectives. First, to achieve self-sufficiency in production, as well as ensuring strategic independence from major technology exporters such as Germany, Japan, South Korea and the US. Second, supplement the huge domestic market with greater external demand through instruments such as the Belt and Road Initiative, which aims to open up markets in the emerging world under the banner of a supposed inclusive globalization. It is no coincidence that the Chinese government has taken up the rhetoric of “win-win” to claim the alternative to the current Western-led globalization. In 2013, President Xi Jinping declared that China would promote «peaceful cooperation, openness and inclusion, mutual learning and mutual reference, mutual benefit and win-win, to promote all-round pragmatic cooperation and build the community of common interest» (Chen, 2018, p.828). Disenchanted scholars have said that this “win-win” will mean 2:0 for China (Kołodko, 2018), but the idea has caught on.

The US and European response can be summarized within the framework of the Sullivan Doctrine and the EU's De-Risking Doctrine, which adopt a confrontational policy approach similar to that of China (Ciuriak, 2023). These doctrines involve an industrial policy aimed at securing significant shares of future industries within one's own country and seek to exploit existing assets to engage in technology wars while reducing exposure to supply chain disruptions resulting from geopolitical conflicts.

Relevant policies entail significant costs to public finances, both in terms of subsidies for industrial restructuring and compensation for efficiency losses due to foregoing the benefits of the international division of labor. In the US, government incentives have historically been effective in influencing the location of factory within the country, but they have never been sufficient to overcome the cost gap with lower labor cost countries. Now, federal subsidies (particularly those related to the Chips Act and IRA) are substantial and sufficient to close the gap, thus becoming a powerful catalyst for re-shoring (Reshoring Initiative, 2023). As for Europe, Sandkamp (2022) simulated the effects of decoupling from GVCs if imposed “by decree.” Under all scenarios assumed for different decoupling between Europe, the US, China, Russia and the rest of the world, the results show that Europe would experience a decrease in real income. Moreover, while reducing reliance on third countries, decoupling would make Europe more vulnerable to market shocks, thereby eliminating the “insurance” provided by international trade for urgently needed products during domestic crises.

Finally, as part of a politics-driven industrial policy, nation-states implement government-business coordination mechanisms for the transformation of their national champions into world-class MNEs, by supporting their entry into foreign markets and safeguarding them from foreign competitors in the domestic market through direct and indirect subsidies and regulation of competition (see Section 3.4). Often, favorable conditions of near-monopolistic control of domestic markets provide economic rents for firms to undertake international operations.

At the heart of this orchestration are state-owned enterprises (SOEs) and hybrid enterprises co-owned by the state, private firms and financial institutions. In the latter governments play a leadership role in a coalition of blockholders through control-enhancing mechanisms, such as golden shares, cross-shareholdings, pyramids and other share manipulation techniques (Bruton et al., 2015; Mariotti and Marzano, 2020). These firms benefit from government-related resource (substantial budget, soft financial constraints, government financial bailouts, low-cost loans, subsidies) and access to foreign political institutions (Mariotti and Marzano, 2019). Moreover, as nominal providers, SOEs can act as conduits for government subsidies so that other SOEs and private firms can be subsidized nontransparently as ultimate recipients. Overall, policies promoting SOEs and hybrid firms create negative externalities in international markets, resulting in distortions of trade and investment (Borlini and Silingardi, 2023).

Serious concerns have also raised about SOEs as tools for pursuing political and military objectives (geopolitical influence, espionage, illicit transfer of critical technologies). Particularly in the West, these concerns have focused on China because of its unique governance system, which grants the government a high level of control over SOEs, but also over private firms through golden shares and an institutional “rule-by-law authoritarianism” that prevent firms from maintaining their autonomy through constitutionally enshrined rights. Evidence of the Chinese government's extensive use of SOEs for political purposes, including economic coercion, further amplifies the perception of potential risks involved (McDonagh, 2023).

3.4 The misuse of antitrust and industry regulation

Competition policies, which include ex-ante industrial regulation and ex-post antitrust measures, are Janus-faced vis-à-vis FDI. Their mission is to protect competition and establish a level playing field for all investors, domestic and foreign. However, the indefiniteness and ambiguities inherent in competition laws leave room for discretionary enforcement and can be abused as a barrier to FDI (Mariotti, 2023).

Although in most countries the enforcement of competition laws is entrusted to independent authorities, the latter can be captured by governments, leading to the expropriation of their independence and the erosion of their functions in the name of national interest. In turn, governments can be pressured by groups representing vested interests (Gardbaum, 2020). More subtly but impactful, authorities can be “culturally” captured, i.e. persuaded to adopt the thinking and fulfill the agenda of national elites who have gained ideological and political dominance within the country (Kwak, 2013).

In the postwar period, several countries – including the EU, Japan and China – have been accused of abusing competition policy to shield domestic industry from foreign entries. In win-lose globalization, the phenomenon has become widespread and intensified (Mariniello et al., 2015), due to nation-states adopting policies that abuse antitrust and regulation to influence international movements of goods and capital for their own benefit. The lack of international enforcement of competition laws makes the authorities subject only to national jurisdiction. Therefore, governments may circumvent the constraints, limitations and lengthy legal processes that, despite increasing difficulties (see previous Section), multilateral institutions and the network of international trade and investment agreements still impose on individual nations (Murray, 2019). Indeed, attempts to establish supranational bodies with the authority to enforce binding global competition rules and to prevent and sanction violations have failed over time. The WTO itself has given up on the idea of taking on such a role. Only one voluntarily created institution – the International Competition Network – remains on the scene. The latter provides recommendations on best practices and exerts peer pressure on deviant countries, but is powerless in the face of individual countries' manipulative choices.

Misuses of antitrust and regulation are common in countries ruled by populist or authoritarian regimes. Bernatt (2022) illustrates how, despite being subject to EU jurisdiction, Poland and Hungary have enacted policies that have undermined the actions of national regulatory and competition authorities. These policies include: limiting their independence; decreasing the resources allocated to their operation; weakening the enforcement effort, especially with regard to SOEs and large domestic firms; and granting the government discretion to exempt certain transactions from merger control on the basis of national interest. China has also used competition law as a powerful economic weapon, especially during the Sino-US technology war. Zhang (2021) explores this strategic application through numerous case studies. The author documents the wide administrative discretion possessed by the Chinese government, to the point that agencies can even exploit the media to pursue hostile enforcement.

This trend has involved democracies in advanced countries. In the US, increased government interference in competition policies has persisted. Authorities are being pushed to address social issues arising from market concentration, such as disparities to the detriment of workers, small businesses and consumers. The promotion of “socially responsible” agencies and the creation of an antitrust position in the White House have strong potential to undermine the independence of the Federal Trade Commission (FTC), paving the way for government interventionism. In this regard, the “Omnibus Bill 2023” signed into law by President Biden is noteworthy because it links antitrust considerations with national security by mandating coordination between the FTC and the US Department of Justice (DOJ, the other agency for competition law enforcement) and CFIUS. This enables the authorities to identify antitrust violations through access to confidential information. Equally important is the creation of a channel through which regulators will receive advice and pressure from their national security counterparts, thereby influencing their decision-making.

4. What next for interstate rivalry

Some views attribute events deemed extraordinary, such as the pandemic and the Russian-Ukrainian war, as the causes of global economic turmoil (Pindyuk, 2022). Another perspective recognizes a shift in the world order, but one that involves temporary instability until international relations find an adjustment. These explanations offer limited insights into the long term developments. Both seem to suggest that once the storm subsides, win-win globalization will return, thanks to a multipolar equilibrium in which emerging powers will see their role recognized. Unfortunately, in light of our interpretation and the macroeconomic forecasts of international analysts, the prospect of an “old normal” seems unlikely.

Although long-term forecasts should be taken with a grain of salt, all leading institutions agree in predicting a slowdown in the growth rate of the world economy in the coming decades. The OECD predicts a decline in the growth trend of real world GDP to 2% annually by about 2060 (Guillemette and Turner, 2018), while Goldman Sachs forecasts a decline to 1.7% in 2080, from about 3.5% today (Daly and Gedminas, 2022). This slowdown is attributed to a combination of demographic factors and the deceleration in global productivity growth. As for world population, its annual growth rate is declining almost linearly from its peak of 2.3% in 1963 to the current 0.9% and is expected to approach zero in 2075 and turn negative (−0.1%) before 2100 (United Nations, 2022). With regard to productivity, the main explanation is the slowdown in technological progress, based on the techno-pessimistic view that recent innovations contribute less to productivity growth than in the past (Summers, 2015) and the assumption of stagnation in the international movement of technologies, data and ideas.

This global slowdown indicates that the ongoing interstate competition will not only persist, but intensify, changing the balance of power. Scenarios indicate that by 2050 the top five economies will be China, the US, India, Indonesia and Germany; and by 2075, Nigeria, Pakistan, Egypt and Brazil are expected to surpass Germany, Japan and the UK. Although these predictions may be contradicted to some extent, they foreshadow years of fierce competition among countries. Furthermore, pessimistic views are put forward by international relations scholars. The Munich Security Report 2024 points out that «as more and more states define their success relative to others, a vicious cycle of relative-gains thinking, prosperity losses, and growing geopolitical tensions threatens to unroll. The resulting lose-lose dynamics are already unfolding in many policy fields and engulfing various regions» (Bunde et al., 2024). Armstrong and Quah (2023, p.3) argue that the current competition between major powers is leading to epic fail due to a “lose-lose” cycle such that «geopolitical rivalry emerges; economics is weaponized; national security concerns mount and geopolitical rivalry sharpens yet further».

One might adopt a skeptical attitude in the face of these predictions, but wisdom suggests taking proactive measures to change the course or mitigate its negative consequences. Win-lose globalization could worsen unless governments agree to introduce radical reforms of key institutions responsible for the international governance of political relations. Achieving these results depends on symmetry of behavior among nation-states. The renunciation of competition and limitation of interventionist policies by one government must be reciprocated by similar commitments by other governments. To avoid the epic fail, governments must recognize the domestic costs associated with engaging in strategic rivalry (e.g. see Section 3.3). This implies recognition of the risks posed to their economies by the widespread application of aggressive national interventionism.

5. Conclusion

In this paper, I propose a critical interpretation of the evolution of globalization based on some main empirical evidence. First, since the 2008 GFC, the FDI regime has shifted from a phase of near-exponential growth to one of high volatility and uncertain trends; this shift parallels the strong recovery of greenfield projects in recent years. The latter indicates how the widening of global interdependencies persists, but with a geographic repositioning of major investors. Second, countries are more determinedly exercising their national sovereignty over the main drivers of globalization–trade and FDI–by taking protectionist and other measures to restrict/regulate related flows. Third, highly sensitive areas of international competition, such as industrial and trade policy and regulation, are increasingly affected by the interventionist actions of nation-states.

Leveraging the IB and international economics criticism on the redistributive inequalities of globalization and sharing the thesis of growing anarchy in international relations, the paper links and interprets these stylized facts as a consequence of a “win-lose” reshaping of globalization. In this regard, the main takeaways are as follows.

The intertwining and intensification of competition among firms and between rival states is a consequence of the sustained growth of the global economy over several decades. This growth has led to the crowding out of ambitious new world-class MNEs and the emergence of new superpowers and middle powers. Illusory dreams of a peacefully integrated world (Fukuyama's end of history) in which stateless enterprises thrive have given way to a reality of nation-states employing a vast armamentarium of policies to capture markets and contain the expansionism of rival states. The alarming chaotic patterns observed in movements of both capitals and tangible and intangible goods and resources result from this evolution.

The “win-lose” perspective is a better interpretation than deglobalization or slowbalization, which evoke a reversal or a slowdown of globalization. Indeed, decoupling and “-shorings” should not be interpreted only as attempts by nation-states to just pursue defensive isolationist perspectives. On the contrary, these industrial restructurings often reflect an offensive attempt to prevent rival states from gaining future access to strategic knowledge for international supremacy while creating market opportunities for their national champions. The weaponization of economic policies described in the previous pages indicates a different state strategy than in past developmentalism, which was aimed at strengthening the domestic economy rather than weakening rival states. In this sense, the “win-lose” perspective contributes to the strand of research into the reshaping of globalization, deepening and consolidating the idea of its emerging confrontational nature, with an increasing number of countries pursuing “tit-for-tat” nationalist policies (Petricevic and Teece, 2019).

According to the paper's arguments, the prospects for a return to win-win globalization are low, while interstate competition and conflicts in international relations are likely to intensify. However, it is not inevitable that this trend will become irreversible, and some related policy implications can be drawn.

In the absence of a hegemonic governing power, a reevaluation of international institutions in various political (and military) spheres is necessary to address the anarchy of competition between firms and between nation-states. These institutions should focus on facilitating communication, reducing uncertainty about parties' intentions, and enforcing compliance with agreements to foster cooperation among nation-states. The need for supranational bodies and global institutions that monitor transparent national policies and have real powers in areas such as trade, investment, and technology is recognized by IB scholars (e.g. Buckley, 2021). This challenge extends to international relations theory and the debate between structural realism and liberal institutionalism. The latter relies on the rationality of states and the fact that they do not play a one-shot game, but an indefinitely repeated game in which they learn of the existence of superior payoffs associated with cooperation. This creates the conditions for reforming international institutions and avoiding conflict. In response, the realist approach emphasizes that the nation-state's utility function in a noncooperative game is based primarily on “relative” gains. Consequently, strong asymmetries in the distribution of gains can lead to a future that threatens the very existence of disadvantaged states. In other words, anarchy in the international system means not only the absence of an authority capable of enforcing agreements, but also the absence of an authority capable of protecting states. As a result, states will be forced to prioritize their own security and survival. This dramatizes what is at stake in international relations.

In this scenario, restoring the credibility of institutions such as the WTO, IMF, Central Bank (to name a few) is a priority. This implies respecting and strengthening their rules. At the same time, it is necessary to expedite the building of international institutions with supranational enforcement power in crucial areas such as security and public order, FDI regulation, competition policy, technology cooperation, state aid and SOEs, so that violations inspired by selfish interests and global protectionism can be curtailed. Finally, nation-states should develop an awareness that gaining economic and social security by controlling or weakening rival states does not pay, since the disutility produced by the equal reaction of other nations generates high costs in the long run, if not a lose-lose situation; and that implementing decoupling tout court is impossible in a context of inextricable interdependencies. So they should tenaciously seek the balance between economic openness and economic security through international cooperation.

As for MNCs', they should prioritize the development of new capabilities and strategy along three dimensions. In reactive terms, invest in the ability to anticipate changes in international governance that might limit the range of their strategic choices, as well as refine their market assessment to find new growth opportunities and borderless business segments over which nation-state armament cannot impose or has little influence. In adaptive terms, reviewing their management philosophy and organizational models, seeking the balance between global and local footprint best suited to cope with growing protectionism and geopolitical and military risks, as well as to respond to sudden and hostile regulatory and institutional changes. In proactive terms, according to a forward-looking CSR-oriented perspective, MNCs should cooperate with national and international institutions to help reduce the anarchic win-lose dynamic of the world economy, thereby also safeguarding their own welfare.

The academic community must also engage in the collective effort that this policy challenge imposes. A few methodological directions are prioritized in the future IB research:

  • dissect the implications of public interventions involving the international dimension, in order to raise awareness in the business and public communities of the risks some policies pose to economic and social growth;

  • endogenize in conceptual frameworks and models variables that are often assumed to be exogenous, such as in research that merely studies the reactive response of firms to changes in economic, institutional and geopolitical contexts;

  • take into account all the externalities, including intertemporal ones, that individual rational and optimizing business decisions induce on other firms and institutions through feedbacks generated by the multiple interactions between public and private, national and international actors; and

  • challenge conceptual complexity and integrate insights from IB theory, competition economics and policy, and international relations theory to effectively advance the knowledge to be made available to firms, institutional decision makers and politicians.

These directions may seem both obvious and a pipe dream, but their implementation is the main challenge of the coming years, so as to make international cooperation possible. If this goal is not achieved, far more intricate and ominous questions will arise about the fate of the global order, which will remain exposed to competing nationalist inclinations driven by anarchic forces.

Figures

Global FDI flows, 1970–2022 (billion dollars)

Figure 1.

Global FDI flows, 1970–2022 (billion dollars)

Greenfield projects versus cross-border M&As, 2012–2022 (billion dollars)

Figure 2.

Greenfield projects versus cross-border M&As, 2012–2022 (billion dollars)

Changes in national investment policies, 2003–2021 (%)

Figure 3.

Changes in national investment policies, 2003–2021 (%)

Compounded average growth rate of global GDP, trade and FDI (%)

Economic indicator 1990–2007 2007–2014 2014–2022
GDP 5.15 2.00 2.90
Trade 7.90 2.86 2.75
FDI 11.85 –4.50 1.50

Source: Elaborations on UNCTAD database

References

Alvesson, M. and Deetz, S. (2020), Doing Critical Research, Sage, London.

Amighini, A.A., Maurer, A., Garnizova, E., Hagemejer, J., Stoll, P.T., Dietrich, M., Roy, R., Skowronek, A. and Tentori, D. (2023), Global Value Chains, European Union, Bruxelles.

Ando, M., Hayakawa, K. and Kimura, F. (2024), “Supply chain decoupling: geopolitical debates and economic dynamism in east asia”, Asian Economic Policy Review, Vol. 19 No. 1, pp. 62-79.

Antràs, P. (2020), “De-globalisation? Global value chains in the post-COVID-19 age”, Working Paper 28115. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.

Armstrong, S. and Quah, D. (2023), “Economics for the global economic order: the tragedy of epic fail equilibria”, arXiv preprint, arXiv:2310.18052.

Bakas, A. (2016), Capitalism and Slowbalization: The Market, the State and the Crowd in the 21st Century, Dexter, Wellesley, MA.

Baldwin, R. (2012), “Global supply chains”, Discussion Papers 9013. CEPR, London.

Bernatt, M. (2022), Populism and Antitrust: The Illiberal Influence of Populist Government on the Competition Law System, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Beugelsdijk, S. and Luo, Y. (2024), “The politicized nature of international business”, Journal of International Business Studies, doi: 10.1057/s41267-023-00681-4.

Boklan, D. and Bahri, A. (2020), “The first WTO's ruling on national security exception: balancing interests or opening pandora's box?”, World Trade Review, Vol. 19 No. 1, pp. 123-136.

Borlini, L.S. and Silingardi, S. (2023), “The foundations of international economic order in the age of state capitalism”, in Dimitropoulos, G. and Gourgourinis, A. (Eds), State Capitalism and Investment Law, Hart, Oxford, pp. 17-41.

Bruton, G.D., Peng, M.W., Ahlstrom, D., Ciprian, S. and Xu, K. (2015), “State-owned enterprises around the world as hybrid organizations”, Academy of Management Perspectives, Vol. 29 No. 1, pp. 92-114.

Buckley, P.J. (2020), “The theory and empirics of the structural reshaping of globalization”, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 51 No. 9, pp. 1580-1592.

Buckley, P.J. (2021), “Exogenous and endogenous change in global value chains”, Journal of International Business Policy, Vol. 4 No. 2, pp. 221-227.

Buckley, P.J. (2023), “Corporate reactions to the fracturing of the global economy”, International Business Review, Vol. 32 No. 6, p. 102014.

Bunde, T., Eisentraut, S. and Schütte, L. (2024), “Munich security report 2024: lose-lose?”, MSC: Munich Security Conference, 2024.

Cerny, P.G. (1997), “Paradoxes of the competition state: the dynamics of political globalization”, Government and Opposition, Vol. 32 No. 2, pp. 251-274.

Chen, Z. (2018), “The practical way of the community of common destiny for all mankind. An analysis of one belt and one road”, Proceedings of 2nd International Conference on Culture, Education and Economic Development of Modern Society (ICCESE), Atlantis Press, Amsterdam, pp. 827-831.

Chiang, J.T. (1991), “From ‘mission-oriented’ to ‘diffusion-oriented’ paradigm: the new trend of US industrial technology policy”, Technovation, Vol. 11 No. 6, pp. 339-356.

Christen, L. (2023), “The global supply chain challenge. An analysis of global supply chain vulnerabilities and how to resolve them using the example of the semiconductor industry”, American Council on Germany Research Paper, New York.

Ciuriak, D. (2023), “The economics of supply chain politics: dual circulation, derisking and the sullivan doctrine”, Available at SSRN, doi: 10.2139/ssrn.4433712.

Cui, V., Vertinsky, I., Wang, Y. and Zhou, D. (2023), “Decoupling in international business: the ‘new’ vulnerability of globalization and MNEs’ response strategies”, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 54 No. 8, pp. 1562-1576.

Dabic, M., Maley, J. and Novak, I. (2021), “An analysis of globalisation in international business research 1993–2018: rise of the sceptics”, Critical Perspectives on International Business, Vol. 17 No. 3, pp. 444-462.

Daly, K. and Gedminas, T. (2022), “The path to 2075. Slower global growth, but convergence remains intact”, Goldman Sachs Economics Research, 6 December, New York.

Dettoni, J. (2024), “The five forces that will shape FDI in 2024”, fDi Intelligence, January, p.3.

Enderwick, P. and Buckley, P.J. (2020), “Rising regionalization: will the post-COVID-19 world see a retreat from globalization?”, Transnational Corporations Journal, Vol. 27 No. 2, pp. 99-112.

Ergas, H. (1987), “Does technology policy matter?”, in Guile, B.R. and Brooks, H. (Eds), Technology and Global Industry: Companies and Nations in the World Economy, National Academy Press, Washington, DC, pp. 191-238.

Evenett, S.J. and Fritz, J. (2022), Emergent Digital Fragmentation the Perils of Unilateralism: A Joint Report of the Digital Policy Alert and Global Trade Alert, CEPR Press, London.

Friedman, T.L. (2005), The World is Flat: A Brief History of the Twenty-First Century, Farrar, Stoans and Giroux, New York, NY.

Fukuyama, F. (1992), The End of History and the Last Man, Free Press, New York, NY.

Galeotti, M. (2022), The Weaponization of Everything: A Field Guide to the New Way of War, Yale University Press, New Haven.

Gardbaum, S. (2020), “Comparative political process theory”, International Journal of Constitutional Law, Vol. 18 No. 4, pp. 1429-1457.

Goldberg, P.K. and Reed, T. (2023), “Is the global economy deglobalizing? And if so, why? And what is next?”, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 10392, Washington.

Guillemette, Y. and Turner, D. (2018), The Long View: Scenarios for the World Economy to 2060, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Haskel, J. and Westlake, S. (2017), Capitalism Without Capital: The Rise of the Intangible Economy, Princeton University Press, Princeton.

Havercroft, J. and Prichard, A. (2017), “Anarchy and international relations theory: a reconsideration”, Journal of International Political Theory, Vol. 13 No. 3, pp. 252-265.

Helleiner, E. (2021), “The return of national self-sufficiency? Excavating autarkic thought in a de-globalizing era”, International Studies Review, Vol. 23 No. 3, pp. 933-957.

Hennart, J.F. and Sutherland, D. (2022), “International business research: the real challenges are data and theory”, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 53 No. 9, pp. 2068-2087.

Johnson, C. (1982), MITI and the Japanese Miracle: The Growth of Industrial Policy, 1925–1975, Stanford University Press, Stanford.

Keohane, R.O. (1984), After Hegemony. Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy, Princeton University Press, Princeton.

Keohane, R.O. and Nye, J.S. Jr (2000), “Globalization: what's new? What's not (and so what?)”, Foreign Policy, No. 118, pp. 104-119.

Kleimann, D., Poitiers, N., Sapir, A., Tagliapietra, S., Véron, N., Veugelers, R. and Zettelmeyer, J. (2023), “How Europe should answer the US inflation reduction act”, Bruegel Policy Contribution, 04/23.

Kołodko, G.W. (2018), “Socialism, capitalism, or chinism?”, Communist and Post-Communist Studies, Vol. 51 No. 4, pp. 285-298.

Kritikos, A. and Pagoulatos, G. (2023), “Made in Europe: an EU green industrial plan to respond to the challenge of US and chinese protectionism”, Hellenic Foundation for European and Foreign Policy, Policy Paper, Vol. 123.

Kwak, J. (2013), “Cultural capture and the financial crisis”, in Carpenter, D. and Moss, D.A. (Eds), Preventing Capture: Special Interest Influence in Legislation, and How to Limit It, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 71-98.

Lai, K. (2021), “National security and FDI policy ambiguity: a commentary”, Journal of International Business Policy, Vol. 4 No. 4, pp. 496-505.

Laudicina, P.A. and Peterson, E.R. (2016), “‘From globalization to islandization’, global business policy council, kearney research report”, available at: www.kearney.com/service/global-business-policy-council/article/-/insights/from-globalization-to-islandization (accessed 25 April 2024).

Lee, J. and Maher, R. (2022), “US economic statecraft and great power competition”, Business and Politics, Vol. 24 No. 4, pp. 332-347.

Lenway, S.A. and Murtha, T.P. (1994), “The state as strategist in international business research”, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 25, pp. 513-535.

Luo, Y. (2022), “Illusions of techno-nationalism”, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 53 No. 3, pp. 550-567.

Luo, Y. and Van Assche, A. (2023), “The rise of techno-geopolitical uncertainty: implications of the United States CHIPS and science act”, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 54 No. 8, pp. 1423-1440.

Mariniello, M., Neven, D. and Padilla, J. (2015), “Antitrust, regulatory capture and economic integration”, Bruegel Policy Contribution, No. 11, pp. 1-12.

Mariotti, S. (2022), “A warning from the Russian–Ukrainian war: avoiding a future that rhymes with the past”, Journal of Industrial and Business Economics, Vol. 49 No. 4, pp. 761-782.

Mariotti, S. (2023), “Competition policy in the new wave of global protectionism. Prospects for preserving a FDI-friendly institutional environment”, Journal of Industrial and Business Economics, Vol. 50 No. 2, pp. 227-241.

Mariotti, S. and Marzano, R. (2019), “Varieties of capitalism and the internationalization of state-owned enterprises”, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 50 No. 5, pp. 669-691.

Mariotti, S. and Marzano, R. (2020), “Relational ownership, institutional context, and internationalization of state‐owned enterprises: when and how are multinational co‐owners a plus?”, Global Strategy Journal, Vol. 10 No. 4, pp. 779-812.

Mattson, G. (2020), “Weaponization: ubiquity and metaphorical meaningfulness”, Metaphor and Symbol, Vol. 35 No. 4, pp. 250-265.

Mazzucato, M. (2021), Mission Economy: A Moonshot Guide to Changing Capitalism, Penguin Random House, London.

McDonagh, N. (2023), “Protection or protectionism? State-driven foreign investment risks and the EU’s new investment screening measures”, in Hillebrand Pohl J., Warchol, J., Papadopoulos, T. and Wiesenthal, J. (Eds), Weaponising Investments, Springer, Cham, pp. 59-78.

Meyer, K.E. and Li, C. (2022), “The MNE and its subsidiaries at times of global disruptions: an international relations perspective”, Global Strategy Journal, Vol. 12 No. 3, pp. 555-577.

Murray, A. (2019), “Given today’s new wave of protectionism, is antitrust law the last hope for preserving a free global economy or another nail in free trade’s coffin?”, Loyola of Los Angeles International and Comparative Law Review, Vol. 42 No. 1, pp. 117-146.

Murtha, T.P. and Lenway, S.A. (1994), “Country capabilities and the strategic state: how national political institutions affect multinational corporations' strategies”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 15 No. S2, pp. 113-129.

Napolitano, G. (Ed.) (2019), Foreign Direct Investment Screening, Il Mulino, Bologna.

Ohmae, K. (1990), The Borderless World: Power and Strategy in the Interlinked Economy, Free Press, New York, NY.

Petricevic, O. and Teece, D.J. (2019), “The structural reshaping of globalization: implications for strategic sectors, profiting from innovation, and the multinational enterprise”, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 50 No. 9, pp. 1487-1512.

Pindyuk, O. (2022), “Russia’s war in Ukraine causes a reversal of FDI trends”, WIIW Monthly Report on FDI in Central, East and Southeast Europe, 11/2022.

Reshoring Initiative (2023), “2022 Data report”, available at: https://reshorenow.org/content/pdf/2022_Data_Report.pdf (accessed 25 April 2024).

Rodrik, D. (2002), “Globalization for whom”, Harvard Magazine, Vol. 104 No. 6, pp. 29-31.

Rodrik, D. (2008), “The death of the globalization consensus”, Project Syndicate, Jul 11.

Rodrik, D. (2017), Straight Talk on Trade: Ideas for a Sane World Economy, Princeton University Press, Princeton.

Ruigrok, W. and Van Tulder, R. (2013), The Logic of International Restructuring: The Management of Dependencies in Rival Industrial Complexes, Routledge, London.

Sacerdoti, G. and Borlini, L.S. (2023), “Systemic changes in the politicization of the international trade relations and the decline of the multilateral trading system”, German Law Journal, Vol. 24 No. 1, pp. 17-44.

Sandkamp, A. (2022), “Reshoring by decree? The effects of decoupling Europe from global value chains”, Intereconomics, Vol. 57 No. 6, pp. 359-362.

Seidl, T. and Schmitz, L. (2023), “Moving on to not fall behind? Technological sovereignty and the ‘geo-dirigiste’ turn in EU industrial policy”, Journal of European Public Policy, doi: 10.1080/13501763.2023.2248204.

Stiglitz, J.E. (2017), “The overselling of globalization”, Business Economics, Vol. 52 No. 3, pp. 129-137.

Summers, L.H. (2015), “Demand side secular stagnation”, American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 105 No. 5, pp. 60-65.

UNCTAD (2023), World Investment Report 2023, United Nations Publication, Geneva.

United Nations (2022), World Population Prospects 2022, Summary of Results. United Nations, New York, NY.

Wade, R. (2010), “Is the globalization consensus dead?”, Antipode, Vol. 41 No. s1, pp. 142-165.

Waltz, K.N. (1979), Theory of International Politics, Addison-Wesley, Reading, MA.

Waltz, K.N. (1999), “Globalization and governance”, PS: Political Science and Politics, Vol. 32 No. 4, pp. 693-700.

Weiss, L. (1998), The Myth of the Powerless State, Cornell University Press, Ithaca, New York, NY.

Williamson, J.G. (2005), “Winners and losers over two centuries of globalization”, in UNU-WIDER (Ed.), Wider Perspectives on Global Development, Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke, pp. 136-174.

Witt, M.A. (2019), “De-globalization: theories, predictions, and opportunities for international business research”, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 50 No. 7, pp. 1053-1077.

Witt, M.A., Lewin, A.Y., Li, P.P. and Gaur, A. (2023), “Decoupling in international business: evidence, drivers, impact, and implications for IB research”, Journal of World Business, Vol. 58 No. 1, p. 101399.

Zhang, A.H. (2021), Chinese Antitrust Exceptionalism: How the Rise of China Challenges Global Regulation, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Acknowledgements

Competing interests: The author declares none.

Corresponding author

Sergio Mariotti can be contacted at: sergio.mariotti@polimi.it

Related articles