Abstract
We present an approach for pricing American put options with a regime-switching volatility. Our method reveals that the option price can be expressed as the sum of two components: the price of a European put option and the premium associated with the early exercise privilege. Our analysis demonstrates that, under these conditions, the perpetual put option consistently commands a higher price during periods of high volatility compared to those of low volatility. Moreover, we establish that the optimal exercise boundary is lower in high-volatility regimes than in low-volatility regimes. Additionally, we develop an analytical framework to describe American puts with an Erlang-distributed random-time horizon, which allows us to propose a numerical technique for approximating the value of American puts with finite expiry. We also show that a combined approach involving randomization and Richardson extrapolation can be a robust numerical algorithm for estimating American put prices with finite expiry.
Keywords
Citation
Jang, B.-G. and Koo, H.K. (2024), "American put options with regime-switching volatility", Journal of Derivatives and Quantitative Studies: 선물연구, Vol. 32 No. 2, pp. 86-115. https://doi.org/10.1108/JDQS-12-2023-0043
Publisher
:Emerald Publishing Limited
Copyright © 2024, Bong-Gyu Jang and Hyeng Keun Koo
License
Published in Journal of Derivatives and Quantitative Studies: 선물연구. Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence maybe seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode
1. Introduction
The coming of modern option pricing theory, pioneered by Black and Scholes (1973) and Merton (1973), has had a profound impact on both the academic discipline of finance and the practical operations of the financial services industry. The foundation of this theory, rooted in the concept of the absence of arbitrage opportunities, has evolved into a dominant paradigm in the field of finance, as exemplified by seminal works such as Harrison and Kreps (1979) and Dybvig and Ross (2003). This transformative technology for pricing and risk management has empowered financial institutions to develop a diverse array of customized contracts and securities, tailored precisely to meet the unique requirements of their clientele. In this light, option pricing stands as a fundamental cornerstone of modern finance.
In the early stages of option pricing analysis, exemplified by the renowned Black–Scholes formula, a fundamental assumption prevailed: that the volatility of the underlying asset remained constant. Nevertheless, the veracity of this assumption has been cast into doubt, primarily due to compelling empirical evidence revealing that implied volatility, as observed across various strike prices and maturities, does not exhibit constancy.
In response to the challenges posed by this empirical evidence, extensive research endeavors have been undertaken to expand the scope of the Black–Scholes–Merton framework to encompass scenarios featuring randomly fluctuating volatility. Substantial progress has been made in this pursuit, with notable contributions from scholars such as Hull and White (1987), Wiggins (1987), Stein and Stein (1991), Heston (1993), Bates (1996) and Duffie et al. (2000). These efforts have significantly advanced our understanding and modeling capabilities in the context of dynamic and variable volatility in financial markets.
We contribute to the field of option pricing by conducting an investigation into the pricing of American options in the context of stochastic volatility. Our specific focus on stochastic volatility entails a unique characteristic: the volatility of the underlying asset exhibits a binary behavior. It transitions between two distinct states, denoted as the “high volatility regime” (H) and the “low volatility regime” (L), at the occurrence of jumps dictated by an independent Poisson process. The regime-switching volatility model can be considered as the simplest version of the stochastic volatility model. This model is useful when the underlying asset undergoes regime shifts over a period or when the maturity of the underlying asset is long enough so that the option lifetime includes abrupt environmental changes. Compared to parameter-rich volatility models like the Heston (1993) model, it has relatively fewer parameters, making it considerably easier to calibrate from options market data.
However, it is important to note that our model does not encompass the full spectrum of randomness associated with volatility. For instance, it does not account for potential correlations between changes in volatility and alterations in the underlying asset’s price. Nevertheless, our exploration of American option pricing within the context of regime-switching volatility represents an initial step toward comprehending the valuation of American options in the presence of stochastic volatility. This research sets the foundation for further, more intricate models that can capture additional nuances in the relationship between option pricing and the dynamic nature of volatility.
Option pricing in the context of regime switching has attracted the attention of several researchers, including Naik (1993), Chourdakis and Tzavalis (2000), Chourdakis (2001), Campbell and Li (2002) and Edwards (2005). Empirical findings from their work have shown promise, indicating that regime-switching models offer a fitting representation of market data comparable to more intricate models like stochastic volatility models with jumps. The papers, however, has primarily concentrated on European options.
In a distinctive departure, Bollen (1998) introduced a novel approach known as the “pentanomial tree” to calculate the price of American options within a regime-switching framework. While Bollen presented numerical results, analytical solutions were not derived. Building upon this foundation, Bollen et al. (2000) extended the application of Bollen’s pentanomial trees to investigate currency option prices. Duan et al. (2002) have contributed to this field by proposing a numerical methodology for pricing American options in a discrete-time regime-switching volatility model. Similarly, Driffill et al. (2002) have introduced a closed-form solution for perpetual American call options in scenarios where the dividend process follows a regime-switching pattern. Lastly, Guo and Zhang (2004) have made significant strides by deriving analytic formulas for perpetual American put options within the context of regime-switching volatility. These collective efforts have enriched our understanding of option pricing under regime switching and have paved the way for further exploration in this intriguing area of finance.
We establish fundamental theoretical insights within the framework of regime-switching volatility. Specifically, we demonstrate that the price of an American put option can be represented as the combination of a European put option price and the premium attributed to the early exercise privilege. This characterization extends findings established by Kim (1990), Jacka (1991) and Carr et al. (1992) within the context of constant volatility. Moreover, we provide a rigorous proof that the valuation of an American put option constitutes a unique solution to the free boundary value problem. This result builds upon earlier work by Mckean (1965) and Van Moerbeke (1976), expanding its applicability to the regime-switching volatility setting. Furthermore, we delve into the realm of perpetual American put options, demonstrating that their pricing exhibits distinct characteristics across the volatility regimes. Specifically, we establish that perpetual put options command a higher price during periods of high volatility compared to low volatility phases. Additionally, we reveal that the optimal exercise boundary is situated at a lower threshold in high-volatility regimes, as opposed to low-volatility regimes. These findings contribute valuable insights into the dynamics of option pricing in the context of fluctuating volatility regimes (Theorems 3.7 and 3.8).
To facilitate the numerical determination of the American put option’s value, we employ the randomization method introduced by Carr (1998). This method involves substituting the fixed time horizon with a random time, effectively transforming the problem into one that resembles the pricing of a perpetual put option. Consequently, the pricing of an American put option with a specified time horizon, denoted as T, can be approximated through a backward induction process. This process considers a substantial number, N, of randomly generated time points, whose summation is expected to equal the original time horizon T, with a variance equal to T/N. We derive an analytical expression for the value of an American put option with such a random time horizon. Subsequently, we present numerical examples that showcase the robustness of the randomization method in conjunction with Richardson extrapolation. This combined approach serves as a robust algorithm for approximating the price of American put options with finite maturities in the regime-switching model. Our analysis includes a comparative evaluation of the numerical results obtained through this method with those generated using the pentanomial tree proposed by Bollen (1998). Furthermore, we establish a noteworthy observation: the N-th approximation of an American put option with finite maturity consistently commands a higher price during periods of high-volatility compared to low-volatility phases. Additionally, we demonstrate that the optimal exercise boundary is situated at a lower threshold in high-volatility regimes relative to low-volatility regimes (Theorem 4.4) [1].
A paper closely related to ours is Boyarchenko and Levendorskii (2009), which presents an American option pricing framework within the context of Markov-modulated Lévy models, utilizing Carr’s randomization procedure. While our paper shares certain similarities with their work, it distinguishes itself by offering a unique contribution—analytical comparisons of the optional exercise boundaries and option prices, contingent on the volatility regime.
After Boyarchenko and Levendorskii (2009), Huang et al. (2011) introduce iterative procedures to value American options under regime switching. Zhang et al. (2014) exploit a penalty method to solve a system of complementarity problems arising from pricing American options. Yousuf et al. (2015) develop a second-order method based on an exponential time-differencing approach for solving American options under multi-state regime switching. Chiarella et al. (2016) solve the American option pricing problem under regime-switching by using the method-of-lines scheme. Lu and Putri (2020) use the Laplace transform method to solve the system of the partial differential equations for American option pricing. Including these papers, there are numerous papers dealing with the valuation of American options under regime switching. However, most of them do not show analytical comparisons based on the regimes covered in this paper.
The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 explains the model with regime-switching volatility. Section 3 studies a perpetual American put. Section 4 investigates pricing of an American put with finite expiry by randomization of time horizon and Section 5 discusses its implementation and shows numerical examples. Finally, Section 6 concludes. All the proofs are contained in the Appendix.
2. Model
In this section, we explain a model of a financial market. In the model, all activity occurs on a filtered probability space
In the financial market, there are two (underlying) assets. The first asset (the bond) is a money market account and is instantly risk-free. We assume that the return on the riskless asset is constant and equal to r. The second asset (the stock) is risky and American options are written on this asset. The price St of the stock evolves according to the following equation
The volatility of the second asset takes two values σH > σL > 0; namely, there are two regimes, say, “high volatility regime” H and “low volatility regime” L and volatility σH in regime H is larger than volatility σL in regime L, i.e. σH > σL > 0. This assumption implies, in particular,
We assume that there is no market frictions, i.e. no taxes, no transaction costs and no short-sale constraints. Portfolio strategies, consumption processes and self-financing strategies with an initial wealth are defined as in a standard financial model (see, e.g. Chapter 1, Karatzas and Shreve, 1998).
We employ a standard assumption in modern finance, that is, there is no arbitrage opportunity in the financial market. Then, under a suitable regularity condition, there exists a probability measure Q such that for any financial contract
We will assume that the following is valid throughout the paper:
Standing assumption. There is a unique probability measure under which all the price of every financial contract is a martingale. The measure is used for pricing of all securities that will be introduced to the market. Under Q, the intensity of the Poisson process φi is λi for i ∈ {H, L}.
We will call Q the risk-neutral probability measure and the stock price process S(t) satisfies
We now consider an American put option with maturity at T < ∞ and strike price K written on the stock. Suppose that the stock price is equal to S and the volatility regime is i ∈ {H, L} at time 0, then we define
The next proposition shows that our definition of the fair price is equal to the smallest wealth to hedge a short position of the American put if the market is complete. In order to state the proposition, we will consider (possibly non-existent) financial assets Θi for i = H or L whose price is perfectly correlated with the Poisson process φi. The financial market is complete if both ΘH and ΘL are tradable, i.e. the price processes exist and investors can form their portfolios using the assets.
Suppose that the financial market is complete, i.e. for j = H and L the financial contract Θj is tradable in the market. Suppose also that S0 = S, σ(0) = σi(i ∈ {H, L}) Then, Pi(t, S) is equal to the smallest initial wealth required such that there exists a self-financing strategy whose wealth process X(u) satisfies
- (i).
X(u) ≥ (K − S(u))+ for all 0 ≤ u < T.
- (ii).
X(T) = (K − S(T))+ .
Now we state a lemma that will be useful to define the optimal exercise boundaries.
For i ∈ {H, L}, Pi(T, S) is Lipschitz continuous in S, uniformly continuous in T, nondecreasing in T, nonincreasing in S and convex in S.
Let
For i ∈ {H, L}, let us define the optimal exercise boundary
The following theorem states that the American put option price is the sum of the price of a European put option and the premium for the early exercise privilege. The results have been obtained by Kim (1990), Jacka (1991) and Carr et al. (1992) in the constant volatility case. For a measurable set,
For i ∈ {H, L}, let pi(T, S) be the fair price of a European option with a strike price equal to K, time to maturity equal to T and the underlying state S at time T, when the current regime is i. Then,
In the constant volatility case, Mckean (1965) and Van Moerbeke (1976) have shown that the fair value of the American put is a solution to a free boundary value problem. We establish a similar result for the case with regime-switching volatility in the following. Let us define a differential operator
Then, we consider the following free boundary value problem.
Find a pair (fH(u, S), fL(u, S)) of continuous functions defined on
(PH(u, S), PL(u, S)) and
3. Perpetual American puts
In this section, we consider the case where the option’s lifetime is infinite, that is, T = ∞. McKean (1965) and Merton (1973) derived an analytic form for the option price for the case where the volatility is constant. In this section, we derive an analytic form for the value of a perpetual American put as in Guo and Zhang (2004). Furthermore, we provide a result concerning the existence and uniqueness of a solution to the free boundary value problem (Theorem 3.5) and show that the price of the perpetual put is always higher in the high-volatility regime than in the low-volatility regime and the exercise boundary is lower in the high-volatility regime than in the low-volatility regime (Theorems 3.7 and 3.8).
We will use the notation Pi(S) for the value of American put and
Now we consider the following free boundary value problem that will characterize the value of a perpetual American put option.
Find a pair (fH(S), fL(S)) of continuous functions defined on (0, ∞) and a pair
Furthermore,
(PH(S), PL(S)) and
We will later show that
In the following, we will derive the unique solution (PH(S), PL(S)) and
There exist two real negative numbers n1 and n2(n1 > n2) such that a general solution to equations (3.1) for
Suppose that
Now we proceed to determine constants
(i) Both D1 and D2 are positive and (ii) C1 ≠ 0 and C2 ≠ 0.
We now show in the following theorems that the price of the perpetual put is always higher in the high-volatility regime than in the low-volatility regime and the optimal exercise boundary is lower in the high-volatility regime than in the low-volatility regime.
PH(S) ≥ PL(S) for all S > 0 and the inequality is strict for
In Figure 1, we draw a graph of the value of a perpetual American put option where the parameters are given as r = 0.1, K = 1, T = 1, σH = 0.4, σL = 0.2, λH = 1.0 and λL = 0.5. The intensity parameters in the figure are chosen such as the average time it takes a regime to change from high volatility to low volatility is a year, while the average time it takes a regime to change from low volatility to high volatility is half a year. The higher intensity λH in the high volatility regime H is supported by empirical studies, for example, Ang and Bekaert (2002). The result shown in the figure is consistent with Theorems 3.7 and 3.8.
These results are also consistent with our intuition: High volatility yields a higher time value, so the price PH is higher and the corresponding optimal exercise boundary is lower. In the continuation region (the upper region of the optimal exercise boundary), a lower optimal exercise boundary gives the put holder a higher time value because the current stock price is above it.
4. American puts with finite expiry
In this section, we will study the valuation of an American put which has a finite expiration time T. In the case where volatility is constant Carr (1998) has studied the same problem by considering an American put with a random expiration time which is the sum of N independent random times that are identically distributed according to an exponential distribution with a mean equal to T/N. The random time is distributed according to an Erlang distribution with a mean equal to T and a variance equal to T/N, and therefore, the random-time approaches to T in probability as N → ∞. He has suggested that the value of an American put with finite time T to expiration can be approximated by the value of an American put with the previously explained random time if N is sufficiently large. We will apply his technique to study the value of an American put with finite expiry.
4.1 Exponentially distributed time
In this section, we will consider an American put with a random time τ until expiration, where
Note that the expected time to expiration of the American put is β. Analysis of the American put with a random expiration time is very similar to that of the perpetual option in the previous section. As in the case of the perpetual option, the value and early exercise boundary of the American put option are time-homogeneous, i.e. independent of time t, given the volatility regime and stock price. Therefore, the equations describing the fair value of the American put are ordinary differential equations without having time derivatives. We will use notation
As in Carr (1998), the free boundary problem for the fair price of the American put takes the following form: for i, j ∈ {H, L}, i ≠ j,
We will make the following assumption in this section.
There exist four distinct real roots n1, n2, n3, n4 of the algebraic equation IF(n) = 0, where
Note the fact that IF(0) > 0 and IF(1) > 0. Thus, if the roots of equation IF(n) = 0 exist in one of the open intervals (−∞, 0), (0, 1) and (1, ∞), then there are exactly two or four. Assumption I tells us that we assume there exist exactly two roots in (−∞, 0) and the other two roots in (1, ∞), respectively.
Suppose that Assumption I is valid and let ξ1, ξ2, ξ3 and ξ4 be unique solutions to the following equation:
Then the fair value of the American put with random expiration time τ takes the following form.
(i) In the region S > K, for some constants
(ii) In the region
, for some constants and ,
(iii) In the region
, for some constants and ,
There are 10 equations that can be derived from the smoothness of
Suppose that Assumption I is valid. Then,
4.2 Erlang-distributed time
In this section, we will consider an American put with a random expiration time τ which is the sum of N independent random-times which are identically and exponentially distributed with a mean equal to T/N. That is, the American put will expire after the N-th jump time of an independent Poisson process with intensity βN = N/T. Then, τ is distributed according to an Erlang distribution, that is,
Let us consider, N put options with the same strike price K. The first option is the put with an exponentially distributed time to expiration with β = βN explained in the previous section. The k-th option for 1 < k ≤ N is a put which can be exercised for (K − S)+ at any time up to and including the k-th jump time of a Poisson Process with intensity βN, and if the option is not exercised after the k-th jump time of the Poisson Process it becomes the (k − 1)-th put after the jump. Let
If we follow the argument in Carr (1998), we can easily derive the following equation for
Let
The problem is to find
Suppose that Assumption I is valid and the determinant of Φ(1), defined in (6.13), is not zero. Then
(i) In the region
, for two constants ’s(h = 1, 2)
(ii) In the region
, for some constants and and m1, m2 defined in the previous section,
Suppose that Assumption I is valid.
5. Implementation and numerical results
In this section, we will show numerical results. First, we will propose the Richardson extrapolation together with the values of American puts with a random expiration time studied in the previous section as an approximation to the American option with finite expiry. We will compare the solutions obtained from this method with the solutions obtained by pentanomial trees in Bollen (1998) for a certain set of parameter values. Second, we will illustrate behavior of American put values in a regime-switching model with a parameter change by using numerical solutions obtained from the Richardson extrapolation method.
5.1 Richardson extrapolation with randomized put values
We first explain the Richardson extrapolation method. As in the previous section, let Pi(0, S) denote the exact American Put value with time to expiration equal to T < ∞ at time 0 when the stock price is equal to S and regime is i ∈ {H, L}. And let
Table 1 exhibits the value of an American put calculated by the pentanomial-tree method with 103 time steps and those calculated by the method in this paper with three-point Richardson extrapolation. The default parameters are r = 0.1, K = 1, T = 1, σL = 0.2, λL = 0.5. It clearly shows that we can approximate the value of the American put quite accurately by the three-point Richardson extrapolation together with randomized put values (mostly errors are less than 0.0003).
5.2 Characteristics of American put values
Figure 2 shows the value of an American put option as a function of volatility σH of the stock in state H for the following parameter values: r = 0.1, K = 1, T = 1, σL = 0.2, λH = 2.0, λL = 0.5 and S = 0.9. It shows the values in both the high-volatility state and low-volatility state increase as the high-state volatility σH increases.
Figure 3 shows the value of an American put option as a function of volatility σL of the stock in state L for the following parameter values: r = 0.1, K = 1, T = 1, σH = 0.4, λH = 2.0, λL = 0.5 and S = 0.9. It shows the values in both the high-volatility state and low-volatility state increase as the low-state volatility σL increases. Put prices tend to increase as either the high-state volatility or the low-state volatility increases.
The results in Figures 2 and 3 are because there is a possibility that the future regime may differ from the current regime through regime shifts, thus the option price in a regime might be highly influenced by the volatility of the opposite regime. This implies, if a period incorporating regime shifts is considered as the lifetime of an American option, practitioners should assess the market value of options taking into account the volatility of a regime different from the present one.
Figure 4 shows the value of an American put option as a function of intensity parameter λH for the following parameter values r = 0.1, K = 1, T = 1, σH = 0.4, σL = 0.2, λL = 0.5 and S = 0.9. It shows the values in both the high-volatility state and low-volatility state decline as the intensity λH increases. Namely, as it is more likely for the high-volatility regime to change to the low-volatility regime, the option values in both the high-volatility state and low-volatility state tend to decline. Figure 5 shows the value of an American put option as a function of intensity parameter λL for the following parameter values r = 0.1, K = 1, T = 1, σH = 0.4, σL = 0.2, λH = 2.0 and S = 0.9. It shows the values in both the high-volatility state and low-volatility state increase as the intensity λL increases.
We conjecture the above comparative statics results illustrated by numerical examples are generally valid and leave their analytic proof as an open question.
6. Conclusion
We introduce a novel approach to find the value of American puts with regime-switching volatility. We demonstrate that the value of an American put can be represented as the combination of the corresponding European put price and the premium attributed to the early exercise privilege. We also provide rigorous proof that the American put value constitutes a unique solution to the free boundary value problem. Furthermore, we show that perpetual American put options can exhibit distinct characteristics depending on the prevailing volatility regime. Specifically, we establish that perpetual put options command a higher price during periods of high-volatility compared to low-volatility phases. Additionally, we reveal that the optimal exercise boundary is situated at a lower threshold in high-volatility regimes, as opposed to low-volatility regimes. These findings contribute valuable insights into the dynamics of option pricing in the context of fluctuating volatility regimes.
Moreover, we develop an analytical framework to describe American puts with an Erlang-distributed random-time horizon, which allows us to propose a numerical technique for approximating the value of American puts with finite expiry. We also show that a combined approach involving randomization and Richardson extrapolation can be a numerical algorithm for estimating American put prices with finite expiry.
Figures
Comparison of the value of an American put option for a set of parameter values with default parameters r = 0.1, K = 1, T = 1, σL = 0.2, λL = 0.5
Parameters | Pentanomial tree | 3-Point Richardson | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
S | σH | λH | PH(0, S) | PL(0, S) | ||
0.9 | 0.4 | 1.0 | 0.1483 | 0.1106 | 0.1483 | 0.1106 |
0.9 | 0.4 | 2.0 | 0.1390 | 0.1093 | 0.1393 | 0.1094 |
0.9 | 0.5 | 1.0 | 0.1738 | 0.1150 | 0.1737 | 0.1149 |
0.9 | 0.5 | 2.0 | 0.1594 | 0.1128 | 0.1597 | 0.1127 |
1.0 | 0.4 | 1.0 | 0.1015 | 0.0594 | 0.1014 | 0.0592 |
1.0 | 0.4 | 2.0 | 0.0904 | 0.0574 | 0.0905 | 0.0572 |
1.0 | 0.5 | 1.0 | 0.1293 | 0.0660 | 0.1292 | 0.0658 |
1.0 | 0.5 | 2.0 | 0.1128 | 0.0629 | 0.1131 | 0.0626 |
Note(s): The values in Columns 4 and 5 are obtained by the pentanomial-tree method in Bollen (1998) with 103 time steps and those in Columns 6 and 7 are obtained by our accelerated method with a three-point Richardson extrapolation
Source(s): Authors' own work
Notes
Yi (2008) shows the same result with ours.
Analysis in this paper can be easily extended to the case where the stock pays cash dividends at a constant rate.
The probability measure Q is equivalent to P on
We need to enlarge the filtration
The two equations are very lengthy and we do not report them in the paper. They are available from the authors upon request.
We provide proof of the results in this appendix.
The Snell Envelope. Let us define
Proof of Proposition 2.1. The proof is a modification of the proof of Theorem 5.3, Chapter 2 in KS. A self-financing process dominating the American option payoff satisfies the following inequality: there exists some portfolio process (π(t), πH(t), πL(t)), t ∈ [0, T] and γ ∈ R such that for every
Let
Theorem D.13 in KS asserts that ξ(⋅) = M(⋅) − Λ(⋅), where M(⋅) is a uniformly integrable RCLL martingale under Q and Λ(⋅) is an adapted, continuous, nonincreasing process with Λ(0) = Λ(τ*) = 0 a.s. Because of the assumption of market completeness, the
Taking conditional expectations with respect to
Suppose that there exists a self-financing strategy whose wealth process X(t) satisfies (i) and (ii) in the statements of the proposition. For any stopping time
Proof of Lemma 2.2. The proof is essentially the same as that of Proposition 7.1 and Lemma 7.4, Chapter 2 in KS. Therefore, we establish only the proof of the uniform continuity in T here.
Let us define, for i ∈ {H, L},
Then by the bounded convergence theorem,
We need the following lemmas in order to prove Theorem 2.3 and Proposition 2.5.
(PH(u, S), PL(u, S)) is a solution to the initial-boundary value problem
Proof. The proof is a modification of the proof of Theorem 7.6 Chapter 2 in KS.
Consider the following initial-boundary value problem: for i ∈ {H, L}
We know by Lemma 2.2Pi(i ∈ {H, L}) is uniformly Hölder continuous and Theorem 7, Chapter 3 in Friedman (1964) implies that there exists a unique classical solution to the above initial-boundary value problem.
We show that fi = Pi on
By Ito’s rule N(⋅∧ τ) is a bounded P0-martingale, and thus
Now the proof of Proposition 2.1 implies that the stopped process
We now show the last limit in the lemma. Let T ∈ (0, ∞) and for (t, S) ∈ [0, T] × (0, ∞) define
Then,
The Snell envelope ξ(t) has the following decomposition
and
Proof. The proof is a modification of the proof of Theorem 7.9, Chapter 2 in KS. Let
Then,
According to generalized Ito’s rule,
For each u ∈ (0, T), we have
Letting ϵ ↓ 0 in equation (6.4), we obtain (6.3), for
Proof of Theorem 2.3. Suppose that σ(0) = σi(i ∈ {H, L}). By Lemma 6.2, we have
Proof of Proposition 2.5. The proof is a modification of the proof of Theorem 7.12, Chapter 2 in KS. (PH(u, S), PL(u, S)) and
Suppose (fH(u, S), fL(u, S)) is a solution to Problem 2.4 together with
Fix
By using the same argument as in the proof of Lemma 6.2, we obtain
and Λf(⋅) is nondecreasing and defined as
From the fact fk(u, S) ≥ (K − S)+ for k ∈ {H, L} and
Let us now show the reverse inequality. Let
To show that
Proof of Proposition 3.2. We can extend Lemma 6.1 to the case T = ∞ by considering a system of the second-order ordinary differential equations instead of parabolic partial differential equations. Namely, for i ∈ {H, L}
Now (PH(S), PL(S)) and
Conversely, a solution (fH(S), fL(S)) and
Proof of Lemma 3.3. We first try to find a solution of the form PH(S) = Sn, PL(S) = ξSn to (3.1), where n and ξ are some complex numbers. A straightforward calculation shows that if n and ξ satisfy the following system of algebraic equations then PH(S) = Sn, PL(S) = ξSn are solutions to (3.1):
We will now show that all the roots of equation (6.7) are real and exactly two of them are negative. Obviously, n = 1 is a one positive root of equation (6.7). Let
Note that among the solutions of the form PH(S) = Sn, PL(S) = ξSn, only those with negative n satisfy boundary conditions
We know that the homogeneous system of equations (3.1) has a solution space of dimension 4. Suppose that the positive real roots to (6.7) are distinct. Then the basis to the solution space consists of pairs of functions PH(S) = Sn, PL(S) = ξSn with n, ξ satisfying (6.6). Solutions to (3.1) satisfying the boundary conditions
It is easy to show that
Let
The proof is now complete. ♠
Proof of Lemma 3.4.Let us assume
Proof of Proposition 3.5. From the boundary conditions for Pm(S) at
Proof of Corollary 3.6. (i) (3.6) and (3.9) yield the property for D1 and D2 immediately.
(ii) Equation (3.8) implies that both C1 and C2 are non-zero. ♠
Proof of Theorem 3.7. Assume that the converse is true, i.e.
By Lemma 2.2, the value of the American put is a convex function of the underlying stock price S (The lemma is stated for a put option with finite expiry, but the proof is valid also for a perpetual put).
Therefore, Pi,SS(S) ≥ 0 for all
Let g(S) ≡ PL(S) − PH(S). Then, for
Note that k1 > 1 and k2 < 0.
By (3.3), we know that
From (3.3) and the fact that n1, n2, k2 < 0, we know
(6.10), the fact that k1 > 1 and the boundary condition
Therefore,
The proof is complete. ♠
Proof of Theorem 3.8. Let h(S) ≡ PH(S) − PL(S). Then, by an argument similar to the proof of Theorem 3.7, we know that h(S) satisfies the following equation for
Applying a standard argument, we know
By an argument similar to the proof of Theorem 3.7, we can show that
For
The proof is complete. ♠
Proof of Proposition 4.1. The proof is a slight modification of the proofs of Lemmas 3.3 and 3.4. ♠
Proof of Theorem 4.2. The proof proceeds in the same way as that of 3.7 and 3.8. ♠
Proof of Theorem 4.3. (i) Equations in (4.1) are derived in the next in this appendix. Since
(ii) This result follows from a standard argument for a second-order ordinary differential equations. ♠
Proof of Theorem 4.4.
Use mathematical induction on k. Theorem 4.2 establishes the proof for k = 1. The rest of the proof is essentially the same as the proofs of Theorem 3.7 and Theorem 3.8. ♠
Derivation of Equation (4.1). Note that the homogeneous solution of the system of ordinary differential equations is of the following form with four undetermined constants
In order to find the particular solution, we use the method of variation of parameters. We derive the matrix equation
The method of variation of parameters is started by letting
Consequently, the solution is of the form
After immediate calculation, we obtain
References
Ang, A. and Bekaert, G. (2002), “International asset allocation with regime shift”, Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 15 No. 4, pp. 1137-1187, doi: 10.1093/rfs/15.4.1137.
Bates, D.S. (1996), “Jumps and stochastic volatility: exchange rate processes implicit in deutsche mark options”, Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 9 No. 1, pp. 69-107, doi: 10.1093/rfs/9.1.69.
Black, F. and Scholes, M. (1973), “The pricing of options and corporate liabilities”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 81 No. 3, pp. 637-654, doi: 10.1086/260062.
Bollen, N.P.B. (1998), “Valuing options in regime-switching models”, Journal of Derivatives, Vol. 6 No. 1, pp. 38-49, doi: 10.3905/jod.1998.408011.
Bollen, P.B., Gray, S. and Whaley, R. (2000), “Regime-switching in foreign exchange rates: evidence from currency option prices”, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 94 Nos 1-2, pp. 239-276, doi: 10.1016/s0304-4076(99)00022-6.
Boyarchenko, S. and Levendorskii, S. (2009), “American options in regime-switching models”, SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, Vol. 48 No. 3, pp. 1353-1376, doi: 10.1137/070682897.
Broadie, M. and Detemple, J. (1996), “American option valuation: new bounds, approximations, and a comparison of existing methods”, Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 9 No. 4, pp. 1211-1250, doi: 10.1093/rfs/9.4.1211.
Campbell, S. and Li, C. (2002), “Option pricing in regime-switching environments”, Working Paper, Brown University.
Carr, P. (1998), “Randomization and the American put”, Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 11 No. 3, pp. 597-626, doi: 10.1093/rfs/11.3.597.
Carr, P., Jarrow, R. and Myneni, R. (1992), “Alternative characterizations of American put options”, Mathematical Finance, Vol. 2, pp. 87-106, doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9965.1992.tb00040.x.
Chiarella, C., Nikitopoulos, C.S. and Schlögl, E. (2016), “Pricing American options under regime switching using method of lines”, Working Paper, University of Technology Sydney.
Chourdakis, K. (2001), “Volatility persistence, regime switches, jumps and option pricing”, Working Paper, University of London.
Chourdakis, K. and Tzavalis, E. (2000), “Option pricing under discrete shifts in stock returns”, Working Paper, University of London.
Driffill, J., Kenc, T. and Sola, M. (2002), “Merton-style option pricing under regime switching”, Working Paper, University of London.
Duan, J.C., Popova, I. and Ritchken, P. (1999), “Option pricing under regime switching”, Working Paper, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology.
Duffie, D., Pan, J. and Singleton, K. (2000), “Transform analysis and asset pricing for affine jump-diffusions”, Econometrica, Vol. 68 No. 6, pp. 1343-1376, doi: 10.1111/1468-0262.00164.
Dybvig, P. and Ross, S.A. (2003), Arbitrage, State Prices and Portfolio Theory: Handbook of the Economics of Finance, Washington University in St. Louis.
Edwards, C. (2005), “Derivative pricing models with regime switching: a general approach”, Journal of Derivatives, Vol. 13 No. 1, pp. 41-47, doi: 10.3905/jod.2005.580516.
Elliot, R.J. (1980), Stochastic Calculus and Applications, Springer-Verlag, New York.
Friedman, A. (1964), Partial Differential Equations of Parabolic Type, Prentice-Hall, London.
Geske, R. and Johnson, H. (1984), “The American put option valued analytically”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 39 No. 5, pp. 1511-1524, doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1984.tb04921.x.
Guo, S. and Zhang, Q. (2004), “Closed-form solutions for perpetual American put options with regime switching”, SIAM Journal on Applied Mathematics, Vol. 64 No. 6, pp. 2034-2049, doi: 10.1137/s0036139903426083.
Harrison, J.M. and Kreps, D. (1979), “Martingales and arbitrage in multiperiod securities markets”, Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 20 No. 3, pp. 381-408, doi: 10.1016/0022-0531(79)90043-7.
Harrison, J.M. and Pliska, S.R. (1981), “Martingales and stochastic integrals in the theory of continuous trading”, Stochastic Processes and Applications, Vol. 11 No. 3, pp. 215-260, doi: 10.1016/0304-4149(81)90026-0.
Heston, S.L. (1993), “A closed-form solution for options with stochastic volatility with applications to bond and currency options”, Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 6 No. 2, pp. 327-343, doi: 10.1093/rfs/6.2.327.
Huang, Y., Forsyth, P.A. and Labahn, G. (2011), “Methods for pricing American options under regime switching”, SIAM Journal on Scientific Computing, Vol. 33 No. 5, pp. 2144-2168, doi: 10.1137/110820920.
Hull, J. and White, A. (1987), “The pricing of options on assets with stochastic volatilities”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 42 No. 2, pp. 281-300, doi: 10.2307/2328253.
Jacka, S.D. (1991), “Optimal stopping and the American put”, Mathematical Finance, Vol. 1 No. 2, pp. 1-14, doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9965.1991.tb00007.x.
Karatzas, I. and Shreve, S.E. (1998), Methods of Mathematical Finance, Springer-Verlag, New York.
Kim, I.J. (1990), “The analytic valuation of American options”, The Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 3 No. 4, pp. 547-572, doi: 10.1093/rfs/3.4.547.
Lu, X. and Putri, E. (2020), Physica A, Vol. 538, 122968, doi: 10.1016/j.physa.2019.122968.
McKean, H.P., Jr (1965), “Appendix: a free boundary problem for the heat equation arising from a problem in mathematical economics”, Industrial Management Review, Vol. 6, pp. 32-39.
Merton, R. (1973), “The theory of rational option pricing”, Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, Vol. 4 No. 1, pp. 141-183, doi: 10.2307/3003143.
Naik, V. (1993), “Option valuation and hedging strategies with jumps in the volatility of asset returns”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 48 No. 5, pp. 1969-1984, doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1993.tb05137.x.
Stein, E.M. and Stein, J.C. (1991), “Stock price distributions with stochastic volatility: an analytic approach”, Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 4, pp. 727-752, doi: 10.1093/rfs/4.4.727.
Van Moerbeke, P. (1976), “On optimal stopping and free boundary problems”, Archive for Rational Mechanics and Analysis, Vol. 60 No. 2, pp. 101-148, doi: 10.1007/bf00250676.
Wiggins, J.B. (1987), “Option values under stochastic volatility: theory and empirical estimates”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 19 No. 2, pp. 351-372, doi: 10.1016/0304-405x(87)90009-2.
Yi, F. (2008), “American put option with regime-switching volatility (finite time horizon) — variational inequality approach”, Mathematical Methods in the Applied Sciences, Vol. 31 No. 12, pp. 1461-1477, doi: 10.1002/mma.984.
Yousuf, M., Khaliq, A.Q.M. and Liu, R.H. (2015), “Pricing American options under multi-state regime switching with an efficient L − stable method”, International Journal of Computer Mathematics, Vol. 92 No. 12, pp. 2530-2550, doi: 10.1080/00207160.2015.1071799.
Zhang, K., Teo, K.L. and Swartz, M. (2014), “A robust numerical scheme for pricing American options under regime switching based on penalty method”, Computational Economics, Vol. 43 No. 4, pp. 463-483, doi: 10.1007/s10614-013-9361-3.
Acknowledgements
This work was supported by the Ministry of Education of the Republic of Korea and the National Research Foundation of Korea (NRF- 2021S1A5A2A03065678).