Gentrification effects on housing prices in neighbouring areas

Mats Wilhelmsson (Department of Real Estate, Economics and Finance, Royal Institute of Technology (KTH), Stockholm, Sweden)
Mohammad Ismail (Department of Real Estate, Economics and Finance, Royal Institute of Technology (KTH), Stockholm, Sweden)
Abukar Warsame (Department of Real Estate, Economics and Finance, Royal Institute of Technology (KTH), Stockholm, Sweden)

International Journal of Housing Markets and Analysis

ISSN: 1753-8270

Article publication date: 16 August 2021

Issue publication date: 17 June 2022

20239

Abstract

Purpose

This study aims to measure the occurrence of gentrification and to relate gentrification with housing values.

Design/methodology/approach

The authors have used Getis-Ord statistics to identify and quantify gentrification in different residential areas in a case study of Stockholm, Sweden. Gentrification will be measured in two dimensions, namely, income and population. In step two, this measure is included in a traditional hedonic pricing model where the intention is to explain future housing prices.

Findings

The results indicate that the parameter estimate is statistically significant, suggesting that gentrification contributes to higher housing values in gentrified areas and near gentrified neighbourhoods. This latter possible spillover effect of house prices due to gentrification by income and population was similar in both the hedonic price and treatment effect models. According to the hedonic price model, proximity to the gentrified area increases housing value by around 6%–8%. The spillover effect on price distribution seems to be consistent and stable in gentrified areas.

Originality/value

A few studies estimate the effect of gentrification on property values. Those studies focussed on analysing the impacts of gentrification in higher rents and increasing house prices within the gentrifying areas, not gentrification on property prices in neighbouring areas. Hence, one of the paper’s contributions is to bridge the gap in previous studies by measuring gentrification’s impact on neighbouring housing prices.

Keywords

Citation

Wilhelmsson, M., Ismail, M. and Warsame, A. (2022), "Gentrification effects on housing prices in neighbouring areas", International Journal of Housing Markets and Analysis, Vol. 15 No. 4, pp. 910-929. https://doi.org/10.1108/IJHMA-04-2021-0049

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2021, Mats Wilhelmsson, Mohammad Ismail and Abukar Warsame.

License

Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


1. Introduction

Academic literature cites social/cultural factors, economic factors or some combination of both as the primary causes or drivers of gentrification. Rapid job growth, the key driver of gentrification in the inner-city during the gentrification wave from the late 1970s through the 1980s, is crucial for gentrification (Kennedy and Leonard, 2001). Housing market dynamics and tight housing markets, with short housing supply compared to job growth, are critical in generating gentrification and a contributing factor to increasing house prices in urban areas. Moreover, the preferences of certain demographic groups for easy access to city amenities create higher demand-side housing pressures (Kennedy and Leonard, 2001).

In many European cities, gentrification concerns were linked to public policy interventions (Atkinson, 2004). Demographic changes caused an increase in demand following the post-war “baby boom”, where the segment of the population age 25–30 increased. In the 1970s, Britain’s demand from this age group contributed to a rapid rise in housing market prices, accompanied by a sharp decline in family size due to several factors. More women joined the workforce due to increasing rates of divorce and unmarried persons. These factors contributed to a significant increase in the number of small families, consisting of one or two children and contributed to increased demand pressures in central city neighbourhoods (Ley, 1986). The durable racial hierarchy dominates residential selection and leads to gentrifying neighbourhoods (Hwang and Sampson, 2014).

Debates related to gentrification’s impacts have always been distinguished as highly polarised (Easton et al., 2020). Gentrification contributes to revitalising the city’s neighbourhoods and urban development, which increases property values in the gentrifying area. However, few studies tried to explain the increased property values due to gentrification. Atkinson (2004) and Shaw (2010) suggest that having more wealthy householders and the physical rehabilitation of housing in neighbourhoods increases tax revenues and local services associated with further investment. Hence, this will lead to improvement of social mixing and less segregation. Simultaneously, gentrification can impose tremendous pressures and exorbitant costs (rent, taxes and other maintenance costs) on low-income families and elderly residents living on fixed incomes, as well as a loss of affordable housing. That contributes to increasing the “exclusionary displacement” caused by the displacement of low-income residents and changing of the neighbourhood’s cultural fabric and flavour (Chum, 2015; Atkinson, 2004; Kennedy and Leonard, 2001; López-Morales, 2016; Walks et al., 2021).

Although gentrification has been studied for over 50 years, significant complexity and confusion remain in gentrification studies due to differences in the methodology and strategy used to define the gentrified neighbourhoods (Barton, 2016). However, concentrating on demographics in terms of socioeconomic status changes represents gentrification’s best measure (Braswell, 2018). Emphasising demographic changes was the focus of quantitative studies (Barton, 2016), where gentrification is accompanied by increases in the number of households and changes in residential demographic structure. In addition to growing housing stock (Kolko, 2007), income represents the most precise and coherent measure of socioeconomic change (Hedin et al., 2012; Ellen and O’Regan, 2008, 2011; Ding et al., 2016; McKinnish et al., 2010). Therefore, we have used population changes and income as measures of gentrification in our study.

This study’s primary purpose is about how to measure the occurrence of gentrification, estimate the concentration of gentrified areas between 2007 and 2013 and relate gentrification with housing values two years later in Stockholm, Sweden.

The major research questions we seek to answer are:

RQ1.

Where are the gentrified areas in metropolitan Stockholm during the study period?

RQ2.

Is there a relationship between housing gentrification and neighbouring housing prices?

RQ3.

Does proximity to gentrified areas have a positive effect on nearby housing prices? In other words, do the gentrified areas have a positive impact on housing values not only in gentrifying areas but also on housing values in nearby neighbourhoods?

Here, gentrification is defined as the process whereby new high-income households displace low-income households. This process contributes to change the basic features and flavours of that neighbourhood and its residents (Marcuse, 1985; Kennedy and Leonard, 2001; Smith, 1996). The research questions will be addressed using Getis-Ord statistics to identify and quantify gentrification in different residential areas in Stockholm. Gentrification will be measured in two dimensions, change in income and population, between 2007 and 2013. The hedonic price model will be used to explain cross-sectional housing prices (2014–2015). Finally, we will examine the relationship between housing gentrification and neighbouring housing prices; that is, we will include a spatial spillover component in the hedonic price model.

A few studies estimate the effect of gentrification on property values (Guerrieri et al., 2013; Ley, 2002). Those studies focussed on analysing the impacts of gentrification in higher rents and increasing house prices within the gentrifying areas, not gentrification on property prices in neighbouring areas. Hence, one of our paper’s contributions is to bridge the gap in previous studies by measuring gentrification’s impact on neighbouring housing prices. Our study seeks to examine the measurable impacts of gentrification on property values in neighbouring areas for gentrifying areas, not only within gentrification neighbourhoods in Stockholm.

The remainder of the paper is divided into six major sections. Section 2 presents the concept of gentrification. It opens with a review of previous studies on gentrification and its effects. Section 3 explains our research methodology and the different model approaches used. Section 4 describes the different data sets used. Section 5 presents the empirical analysis by analysing gentrification estimated by income and the total population of the city of Stockholm between 2007 and 2013. We examine the causal effect of gentrification on housing prices. Finally, the paper concludes with a discussion of the study’s results and implications in Section 6.

2. Concept of gentrification

The term gentrification was coined by Glass (1964) and was first identified in London during the 1960s. The term was used to describe the “invasion” of traditionally working-class neighbourhoods by middle- and upper-class residents (Ilic et al., 2019; He, 2007; Barton, 2016). It resulted in the displacement of the indigenous low-income residents and changes in the neighbourhood’s socioeconomic character (Barton, 2016). The first definition concentrated on the rehabilitation of existing buildings. The gentrification concept expanded to include new units’ redevelopment as a part of broad urban redevelopment (Rérat et al., 2010).

Hackworth and Smith (2001) have identified three waves of gentrification, the first wave beginning in the 1950s and continuing until the economic recession of 1973. This wave was irregular and state-led, where reinvestment (funded by the public and private sectors) targeted inner-city districts in US, Western Europe and Australia. The state’s intervention was often justified by urban degradation, but it negatively affected the urban low-income class. The second wave from the late 1970s continued almost until the end of the 1980s. This wave was characterised by expansion gentrification and it often materialised during the recovery of real estate markets. Gentrification was integrated into a broader range of economic and cultural processes on the national and global levels (Hackworth and Smith, 2001; Podagrosi et al., 2011). Scott (2019) indicates that widespread and significant gentrification began in the late 1950s and early 1960s in large US cities such as New York.

Since the 1990s, the third wave of gentrification has expanded into inner-city neighbourhoods and the more distant neighbourhoods outside the immediate city centres. With the continuous displacement of the working class from the inner city, effective resistance to gentrification has decreased. The state contributed to the gentrification process more than in the other two waves, fuelling the third wave (Hackworth and Smith, 2001). Immergluck (2009) indicates researchers’ agreement that the third wave saw more state leadership of gentrification (Lees et al., 2008; Smith, 2002).

Atkinson (2004) discusses the possible effects of the gentrified neighbourhood in price-shadowing, such as increased rents and price and policy impacts on adjacent neighbourhoods. Atkinson (2004) also cited studies done by Wyly and Hammel (1999) and Shaw (2000) that aimed to examine the resurgence of gentrification in eight American cities between 1992 and 1997. Wyly and Hammel’s (1999) study showed that gentrified neighbourhoods obtained two and a half times more mortgage loans than homebuyers in the suburbs. This had an impact on neighbouring areas. In some cities, gentrified neighbourhoods surrounded islands of poverty and increased gentrification pressures. Shaw (2000) indicates the impact of the neighbourhoods undergoing gentrification on a deprived area of Sydney’s Aboriginal population, created in the early 1970s and known as “the block”. The transformation of the surrounding areas made The Block appear out of place, and worsened the Block’s economic and social problems, which gentrification was purported to solve.

Hedin et al. (2012) examine the social, geographic change in Sweden’s three largest cities, Stockholm, Gothenburg and Malmö, between 1986 and 2001. The study displays the Swedish housing policies, governed by the market with limited state engagement. In addition to relating the gentrification mappings and low-income filtering to neoliberal housing policies, the study indicated the growth of super gentrification and low-income filtering and that social, geographic polarisation intensified during the study period.

Guerrieri et al. (2013)’s study investigated the extent and nature of urban housing price movements during citywide real estate boom periods. They developed a spatial model that links house prices’ movements in urban neighbourhoods and the gentrification of those neighbourhoods in response to a city-wide housing demand shock. The model is based on the concept of “endogenous gentrification”, the tendency of high-income individuals to move to poor neighbourhoods located directly on the border of affluent neighbourhoods, where people prefer to live next to more affluent neighbours. This in-migration process contributes to increasing house prices in more impoverished neighbourhoods and leads to poorer residents leaving their original neighbourhoods; the proximity to affluent neighbourhoods represents neighbourhood gentrification. The study found that gentrification is higher by 64% for neighbourhoods located within 0.5 miles of affluent neighbourhoods, consistent with Kolko’s (2007) results showing that neighbouring tract income contributes to gentrification and indicated positive inter-neighbourhood spillovers. Gentrification probability was greater in neighbourhoods closer to wealthier neighbourhoods.

Ley et al. (2002) compare the effects of immigration, social polarisation and gentrification upon housing prices in Canada’s principal cities, Toronto and Vancouver. They estimated the three factors’ relative contributions to the changing maps of house values between 1971 and 1996 in both cities. The study showed that house prices between the two cities were consistent in terms of spatial patterns, with a difference in the three factors’ importance at different times and places. In terms of the gentrification effect, their results vary between the two cities. In Toronto, gentrification was not too evident as an effect and showed a weaker positive correlation to house values changes. In Vancouver, all three factors showed modest positive relationships with inflating house values, followed by a weaker gentrification factor.

Although scholars recognise the dangers of displacement as a consequence of gentrification, there is no agreement on the magnitude of influence, which remains a controversial issue. Chum (2015) aimed to examine displacement geography in the city of Toronto from 1999 to 2001. The study indicates a significant relationship between gentrification and evictions. The early gentrification may lead to increased demand for houses and rent increases, which increases the vulnerability of low-income residents to evictions. The study results correspond with Murdie and Teixeira (2011), who uncover the effects of gentrification in west-central Toronto. The results indicated an increase in property values in gentrifying areas, rent increases and loss of affordable housing. Low-income people and immigrants are the most affected in gentrifying areas.

What drives house prices and why can we expect gentrification to affect price levels in a gentrified area and its surroundings? The most obvious factors are population and income changes. More people with higher incomes demand housing in the area in question, which drives up prices. A certain momentum continues to gentrify areas that have begun the gentrification process. In addition to the population and income effect on demand and price, it is conceivable that there will also be a change in preferences, which increases demand further than justified by the population and income impact. Here one can, perhaps, also imagine a certain speculative element. A third reason may be that new housing production triggers the gentrification process in the area. New homes mean that a premium generally increases the price level in the residential area. The increased supply of housing also means a larger basis for private and municipal services of different types. This, in itself, entails price level increases.

3. Methodology

Our primary purpose is to estimate the relationship between housing values and proximity to gentrified housing areas, within and without gentrified neighbourhoods – i.e. any spillover effect. This section will illustrate our research methodology and the different model approaches and regression techniques used to estimate this relationship.

3.1 The gentrification variable

We use Getis-Ord statistics Gi* as a measure of a gentrified residential area to estimate the concentration of gentrified areas (hot spots) in Stockholm in the study period 2007–2013 on two variables, income and population changes.

Getis-Ord statistics Gi* is used to study evidence of identifiable spatial patterns, specified a set of weighted features and distinguish statistically significant so-called “hot spots” and “cold spots”. Besides, it determines and recognises cluster structures of hot and cold spots, concentrations of local observations. Other indices, such as Moran’s I indices, do not distinguish between hot and cold spots. Therefore, we have used a Gi* index. The standard definition of the Getis-Ord Gi* statistic is:

(1) Gi*=j=1nWi,jXj j=1nXj

The sum of the weights (Wi) and the expectation (E) of Gi* are:

(2) Wi=j=1nWi,j  and  EGi*=Win

Gi* is usually standardised based on its sample mean and variance. The standardised Gi* statistic for each feature is a Z score and attached to the statistical significance:

(3) Z(Gi*)=j=1nWi,jXj-X¯j=1nWi,jSnΣj=1nwi,j2-(Σj=1nwi,j)2n-1
where n = the total number of features, Xj = attribute value for feature j, the magnitude of variable X at incident location j over all n (j may equal i), Wij = weight value between feature i and j that refers to their spatial interrelationship. A high positive Z score for a feature indicates a spatial clustering of hot spots, whilst a low negative Z score indicates a spatial clustering of cold spots and a Z score near zero indicates no apparent spatial clustering (Ord and Getis, 1995; Songchitruksa and Zeng, 2010).

3.2 The transaction data and the hedonic price model

The hedonic price model was developed and presented in a seminal article by Rosen (1974). The hedonic method will estimate the impact of area characteristics and proximity to other positive and negative externalities where housing values are related to several characteristics of the home and the residential area. Variables included in the price equation are living area, number of rooms and monthly fees in the apartment model. The distance to the shopping mall and central business district (CBD) will also be included, as well as the distance to different sub-centres of Stockholm. In addition, the distance to hot spots (gentrification) will be included in the model. The model that will be estimated can be illustrated with the below equation:

(4) Pi,t=α+β1Xi,t+β2Si,t-1+β3Di,t+εi

where P is equal to price and X is a vector of housing and neighbourhood characteristics. S is the distance or proximity to the gentrified residential area and D is a vector of binary fixed effects. All letters in Greek are parameters to be estimated and subscript i indicates the number of observations and t indicates the time. Note that the variable S is lagged in time by t − 1 to reduce the problem of endogeneity. The distance between transactions and hot and cold spots has been calculated using ArcGIS, a geographic information system for working with maps and geographic information. It calculates the distance and additional proximity information between the input features and the closest feature in another layer or feature class.

In addition to the traditional hedonic model, we have also estimated a so-called treatment effect (TE) model with and without propensity score (PS) as weights in the regression. The transactions that are considered treatment are within the gentrified area and right on the border. The control area consists of the closest area around the gentrified area. The intention is only to compare those within the gentrified area (treatment) with approximately comparable properties outside the control area using the PS approach. The purpose is to reduce the endogeneity and spatial dependency problems.

3.3 Quantile regression

Quantile regression is used to test the hypothesis that the capitalisation effect of proximity to a gentrified residential area varies in the price distribution. The estimation of quantile regression models explores whether house prices, in the presence of treatment, display an asymmetric behaviour across the price distribution. The quantile regression model is more flexible and more robust to outliers than ordinary least square regression (Koenker and Bassett, 1978) with richer characterisation and description of the data. The quantile regression model can be written as follows:

(5) Pi=α+β1(τ)Xi+β2(τ)Treati+β3(τ)Di+εi
where τ is the quantile of the dependent variable (Kostov, 2009). Quantile regression is based on the minimisation of weighted absolute deviations (Zietz et al., 2008). Recent applications of quantile regression models are, for example, McMillen (2008), Liao and Wang (2012), Zhang and Wang (2016), Zhang (2016), Amédée-Manesme et al. (2016), Waltl (2016) and Yoo and Frederick (2017).

4. Data and descriptive statistics

4.1 Disaggregated data and descriptive statistics

To achieve the study’s purpose, we must integrate information on gentrification and property values within the case study area. Therefore, we have used data on income, population and housing values. The data we have used is spatial and provides information on the population at a disaggregated level for squares measuring 250 m2, where the total number of squares is 2,421. The following sections present the descriptive statistics and explain how we have estimated the concentration of gentrified areas.

To analyse housing gentrification, we have used the information about population income and the total populations of Stockholm presented in Tables 1 and 2.

As Table 1 shows, the average total number of people with income has increased by 9% from 2007 to 2013. The highest increase was for people with upper-middle income and high income in the area from 2007 to 2013 (12% and 11%), whilst the growth of people with lower-middle income and low income in the included area was 8% and 6%, respectively. This indicates an increase in the proportion of high-income people in Stockholm during the study period.

As Table 2 demonstrates, the average total population living in the included area has increased by 10% between 2007 and 2013. Similarly, the average for most population age groups increased, except for the age group 16–19, which decreased by 5%. The rate of increase for age group 20–44 was 24%, accompanied by a 22% increase in the proportion of the population age 0–6, a possible indication of an increase in the proportion of young families in Stockholm between 2007 and 2013. The lowest increase, 7%, was in the age group 45–64.

4.2 The measurement of gentrification

To measure gentrification in Stockholm during 2007–2013, we used the median income and population variables. The following section illustrates how we will estimate the gentrification areas. The first step was to create a dummy variable for income and the total population in 2007 and 2013, as shown in Table 3.

The table presents a dummy variable (0, 1) created for income. The value is equal to zero (0) when income is equal or greater than the income means and value one (1) when income is less than the income mean, where the income mean was for 2007 and 2013 (256.162 and 298.297, respectively). Similarly, a dummy variable was created for the population. The value is equal to zero (0) when the population is greater or equal the population mean and value one (1) when the population is less than the population means, where the population means was for 2007 and 2013 (365.8822 and 401.8842, respectively). The second step to measure gentrification was creating a dummy variable for measuring the change in income and total population during 2007–2013.

Table 4 shows gentrification by income, and a dummy variable (0, 1), that measures the change in income during 2007–2013. The value 1 (gentrification) indicates that median income in 2007 was less than average and in 2013 median income was higher than the average. At the same time, the value 0 (no gentrification) represents two cases. In the first, median income in 2007 and 2013 is higher than the average. In the second case, median income in 2007 is higher than the average and in 2013 less than the average. Similarly, to measure the total population’s gentrification, a dummy variable (0, 1) was created to measure the total population change during 2007–2013, as illustrated in Table 5.

As Table 5 presents, the value 1 (gentrification) indicates that the total population living in the included area in 2007 was less than the average, and in 2013 the total population was higher than the average. In contrast, the value 0 (no gentrification) represents two cases. In the first one, the total population in 2007 and 2013 is higher than the average. In the second case, the total population in 2007 is higher than the average and in 2013 is less than the average.

In the third step, we used Getis-Ord statistics Gi* to estimate the concentration of gentrified areas (hot spots) and non-gentrified areas (cold spots) in Stockholm for the study period 2007–2013. As illustrated in Figures 1 and 2, changes of income and population are measured.

Figure 1 illustrates the results of Getis-Ord statistics (hot and cold spots) analysis for gentrification based on income. The hot spots (Gentrification) are concentrated in Stockholm’s centre, in the Hägersten-Liljeholmen area. In the east of Stockholm, gentrified areas are concentrated in Skarpnäck and Farsta. The cold spots (no gentrification) are concentrated in the west of Stockholm, in Rinkeby-Kista, Spånga-Tensta and Hässelby-Vällingby, as well as cold spots distributed to the north of Stockholm and in parts of Norrmalm and Skärholmen, south of Stockholm.

Figure 2 presents Getis-Ord statistics (hot and cold spots) analysis for gentrification based on population. The hot spots (gentrification) are concentrated in Stockholm’s centre, in the Hägersten-Liljeholmen area. East of Stockholm, hot spots are concentrated in Skarpnäck, Farsta and Enskede.

The gentrified areas (hot spots) with high-income people, especially in the centre and east of Stockholm, are the same spots where the population increased during the study period of 2007–2013. It is notable that the increase in income was accompanied by an increase in the population of the gentrified area. Furthermore, the increase in the market segment of high-income people was also associated with the construction of new buildings of higher quality and price. The cold spots (no gentrification) are concentrated in the west of Stockholm, in Rinkeby-Kista, Spånga-Tensta and Hässelby-Vällingby, the same areas in Figure 1. In the north of Stockholm, the cold spots are parts of Östermalm and, south of Stockholm, Älvsjö.

4.3 The hedonic price model data

The traditional hedonic pricing model will be estimated for the condominium market. Data refer to the period 2014–2015 in the City of Stockholm. The source of the data is Mäklarstatistik AB [1] (Swedish Brokerage Statistics). Since 2005, Mäklarstatistik has been collecting data from home sales that take place via brokers. Almost all brokers in Sweden report their contract data to Mäklarstatistik, enabling them to provide up-to-date and comprehensive price statistics for homes throughout Sweden, and an overall picture of price development in the Swedish housing market. Descriptive statistics regarding the variables included in the hedonic model are illustrated in Table 6.

The table presents descriptive statistics regarding the data on condominium sales. The observed number of apartments amounts to 25,898. The average price is just under SEK3.5m, with a standard deviation of as much as SEK1.6m. The average size of rental apartments is 60 square metres, with a standard deviation of 22 square metres. Condominium owners pay a monthly fee to the building association for maintenance and upkeep. On average, this fee amounts to SEK3,200 with a standard deviation of SEK1,200. The average number of rooms is equal to 2, and the average number of building floors is equal to 4. The vast majority of observations have a city-close location, an average of 48 metres from the CBD, and 42 metres from the closest subway station. The average distance to a gentrified residential area, whether income or population gentrification, amounts to about 1,500 metres.

5. The econometric analysis

The econometric analysis aims to estimate the hedonic equation. We use multi-level analyses to find the empirically best form of the hedonic function. The proximity to income-gentrification and population-gentrification areas will be included as a continuous variable in a hedonic price model, and a binary variable in a so-called TE model.

5.1 The hedonic price equation

Here, we will estimate the hedonic price model. Table 7 shows the results of the multi-level regression models analysis.

In the models presented in Table 7, we can note that the goodness-of-fit models are high at around 84%. All estimated parameters have expected signs and reasonable magnitude. For example, increasing the living area by one square metre increases the price by about 1.3%. The newer the building by a year, the greater the price, by 13%. The same positive effect, when a building has an elevator, increases the price by about 3% and an additional room increases the price by about 4%. The further away from the CBD, the apartment is located, the lower the price, whilst distance from the subway station increases the price.

Table 7 shows an income- and population-gentrified area’s direct effect on house prices. The parameter estimate is statistically significant in all models. It can be observed that location within income gentrified areas has a price level that is 6% higher compared to outside gentrified areas (Model M1) and in Model M3 the estimate is 2%, where the location in population-gentrified areas is also included. Locations within population-gentrified areas, as in Model M2, increase the price by around 8% and in the Model M3 by 6%. Simultaneously, the proximity to income- and population-gentrified areas, illustrated in Figures 1 and 2, increases the price by around 8% (Model M4). What emerges from the results is that housing value in an income- or population-gentrified area affects housing prices. What is also clear is that gentrification based on population movement to a residential area has a more significant impact on future prices than the gentrification of a higher income level in the area. Furthermore, we can note that the joint effect is greater than the individual effects. A contributing reason for this result is that the gentrified areas of the population are probably also connected to increased housing supply, i.e. new buildings have been built in the area. We have certainly underestimated the premium for a newly built housing price model, resulting in the higher estimated price impact. New construction is also certainly associated with the expansion of services in the residential area. It may also have generated higher housing prices in the population-gentrified areas compared to income-gentrified areas.

Table 8 presents the spillover effect models of gentrification measured by income and population on house values within and outside the gentrified area. As above, we can observe a positive and significant direct effect from both income- and population-gentrified areas on house values within the gentrified area. The houses located in the income-gentrified areas M5 and M7 increase in price by around 6% and 3%, respectively. The population-gentrified areas have a positive and significant direct effect on house prices in the gentrified area, where house values increase by 7% in model M6 and by 5% in model M7. The direct effect from both income- and population-gentrified areas (Model M8) increases the price by around 7%. The spillover effect from income-gentrified areas on values outside the gentrified area is not significant in model M5 and has a too small positive effect in Models M7 and M8. The spillover effect from population-gentrified areas on values outside the gentrified area is significant and negative in both models.

The effect of gentrification on nearby residential areas is a bit surprising. When it comes to gentrification because of a change in income, we can state that this effect is only seen within the gentrified area. The effect outside the area is weakly positive, which indicates that housing prices rise further away from the gentrified area. On the other hand, the results suggest that the effect of gentrified areas based on population change is negative, i.e. the further away from the gentrified area the apartment is located, the lower the prices; that is, we can, to a certain extent, observe a spillover effect. As stated above, this may be because of nearby housing construction, which triggered the expansion of local services. New housing construction can bring investments in public transportation, which also increase the value of homes in and around gentrified areas. That the same effect cannot be observed concerning income-gentrified areas is, perhaps, obvious, as gentrification based on income alone does not necessarily entail local service and public transportation investments that spill over into nearby areas.

5.2 An alternative approach: propensity score and treatment effect model

The presented models’ goal is to minimise the endogeneity problem. To achieve this, we have also estimated so-called TE models by creating a binary treatment variable to analyse the relationship between gentrification and housing values. The value of one (1) signifies that the house is within a gentrified area and zero (0) that the house is outside of the gentrified area. To measure the gentrified area’s impact on house value, we have included a buffer zone around the gentrified area. Any housing located within 125 metres of the gentrified area may be considered within the area, and beyond 125 metres considered outside the gentrified area.

As shown in Table 9, two models use the PS methodology and two use the TE model approach. Compared to the earlier models, the control area is reduced to 500 metres from the gentrified area in the two TE models TE1 and TE2. In the two PS models PS1 and PS2, we have included PSs as sample weights, where we first estimate a logistic regression model to calculate the probability of being in the treatment area. Models (1) and (2) refer to gentrified areas by income and Models (3) and (4) refer to the gentrified area by population.

In the TE model presented in Table 9, we can see that the degree of explanation is high. About 80% of price variation can be explained by the variables used. Compared to hedonic models, significantly fewer observations are used in the calculation. Instead of over 23,000 observations, we are here using only around 7–8,000 observations. In these models, we will only include housing located within 500 metres of the gentrified area. We have separated the estimates of proximity into one income-gentrified area and one population-gentrified area.

We can observe that there is a positive effect on housing values within income-gentrified housing areas. House values in the model TE1 increased by 3% and in the model PS1 increased by 2.5%. As well, there is a positive effect on housing values within population-gentrified housing areas, where house values in the model TE2 increased by 3%, whilst the lowest increase in price was 1%, in the model PS2. In the models with TE approach and PS approach, the effect on housing values is the same regardless of whether the area is gentrified in terms of income or population. The results can be compared with models M1 and M2 in Table 7, both reporting a greater effect of gentrification on housing values. However, the results cannot be compared with spillover effects estimated in the M5–M8 models in Table 8.

5.3 Parameter heterogeneity

We also test whether the parameters are constant in the price distribution by estimating a quantile regression model, which is used to describe the distribution of the dependent variable and gives a more comprehensive picture of the effect of the independent variables on the dependent variable. Table 10 shows the results of the quantile regression models analysis.

The quantile regression results show the effect on the housing value from gentrification income and gentrification, where the price effect is generally higher in the lower price levels and stable over the rest of the price distribution. The lowest statistically significant effect for the gentrification population (p < 0.05) in the percentiles is 0.9.

6. Conclusion and policy implications

Demographic and other socioeconomic factors such as household income can lead to different types of gentrification. A better understanding of the gentrification phenomenon is vital in attaining reliable estimates of gentrification’s social impact and its multi-dimensional impact on various neighbourhoods, and for formulating proper strategies and policies essential for sustainable urban development. This study’s primary objective was to establish a plausible relationship between gentrification and property values in certain neighbourhoods in Stockholm municipality.

Using population and income data between 2007 and 2013, we estimated gentrification stemming from population and income increases. In addition to building characteristics, we also considered other control variables such as distance to CBD and subway stations in our hedonic price model. Our results indicate that demographic and income increases potentially contribute to the observed gentrification in certain neighbourhoods in Stockholm municipality. Gentrification because of population increase was slightly higher than gentrification by income during the study period.

Regarding proximity to gentrified areas, our hedonic price model results confirm a potential spillover effect from income- and population-gentrified areas. As other previous studies suggest, our study found that the parameter estimate is statistically significant, indicating that gentrification contributes to housing values near gentrified neighbourhoods. The estimated spillover parameter slightly varied between different models. The hedonic price models have the highest estimated figures (around 6%–8% for gentrification both by income and population), whilst TE models indicate lower estimated figures. Our quantile regression results show that the estimated spillover parameters are constant in the price distribution. In other words, the price effect is generally higher and stable over the entire price distribution.

Gentrification has many consequences, such as increased housing and neighbourhood values, which require sound policies that are beneficial to local municipalities, through tax revenues and homeowners, through rent and price increases. A better understanding of the gentrification spillover effect will enable local municipalities to raise more tax revenue and combat and reduce adverse associated effects of gentrification, such as displacement. Furthermore, it provides insights useful for various neighbourhoods related to housing stock quality and proximity to other desirable neighbourhoods, as well as amenities such as subway stations and commercial centres.

Further studies, exploring whether gentrification by income is because of income increases of pre-gentrification indigenous households or newly arrived households, are needed to address any potential displacement effect.

Figures

Gentrification _income hot and cold spots analysis in the city of Stockholm 2007–2013

Figure 1.

Gentrification _income hot and cold spots analysis in the city of Stockholm 2007–2013

Gentrification _ population hot and cold spots analysis in the city of Stockholm 2007–2013

Figure 2.

Gentrification _ population hot and cold spots analysis in the city of Stockholm 2007–2013

Population income in the municipality of Stockholm in 2007 and 2013

Population income categories 2007 2013
Mean SD Mean SD
Total number of people with income 288.337 346.53 315.57 369.48
Number of people with low income in the included area 73.7791 101.308 77.9654 105.152
Number of people with lower middle income in the included area 56.2398 67.5937 60.9717 71.502
Number of people with upper middle income in the included area 59.378 69.3397 66.3452 75.5665
Number of people with high income in the included area 98.9399 141.137 110.287 155.319
N 2,421 2,421
Notes:

Different income levels measured in 1,000 Swedish kronor are low income (<150), lower-middle (150–250), upper-middle (250–360) and high income (>360). Only income of persons aged 20 and older are considered

The total population of the municipality of Stockholm, 2007 and 2013

Population age categories 2007 2013
Mean SD Mean SD
Total population in the included area 365.882 418.236 401.884 449.505
Age 0–6 30.8507 35.6897 37.5301 44.1648
Age 7–15 30.9552 35.5469 33.8321 35.6653
Age 16–19 15.7306 17.9877 14.9556 17.0603
Age 20–24 22.9672 33.3003 26.4618 33.8161
Age 25–44 125.359 168.56 137.154 177.045
Age 45–64 88.0541 103.344 94.2352 107.204
Age 65–W 51.9658 68.1541 57.7159 76.2803
N 2,421 2,421

Dummy variable for income and the total population in 2007 and 2013

Dummy variable for income_2007 Frequency (%) Mean = 256,162
0 1,353 55.89 Income_2007 >= 256,162
1 1,068 44.11 Income_2007 < 256,162
Total 2,421 100.00
Dummy variable for income_2013 Frequency (%) Mean = 298,297
0 1,391 57.46 Income_2013 >= 298,297
1 1,030 42.54 Income_2013 < 298,297
Total 2,421 100.00
Dummy variable for population_2007 Frequency (%) Mean = 365.8822
0 967 39.94 Population_2007 >= 365.8822
1 1,454 60.06 Population_2007 < 365.8822
Total 2,421 100.00
Dummy variable for population_2013 Frequency (%) Mean = 401.8842
0 939 38.79 Population_2013 >= 401.8842
1 1,482 61.21 Population_2013 < 401.8842
Total 2,421 100.00

Gentrification based on income in the city of Stockholm 2007–2013

Gentrification _
income
Freq. (%) Method Description
0 2,112 87.24 If income_2007 == 0 and income_2013 == 0
If income_2007 == 0 and income_2013 == 1
No gentrification
1 309 12.76 If income_2007 == 1 and income_2013 == 0 Gentrification
Total 2,421 100.00

Gentrification based on population in the city of Stockholm 2007–2013

Gentrification _
population
Freq. (%) Method Description
0 2,200 90.87 If population_2007 == 0 and population_2013 == 0
If population_2007 == 0 and population_2013 == 1
No gentrification
1 221 9.13 If population _2007 == 1 and population_2013 == 0 Gentrification
Total 2,421 100.00

Descriptive statistics (2014–2015)

Variables Mean SD Minimum Maximum
Price 3,456,579 1,650,389 780,000 103,000,000
Living area 60.367 22.229 23 203
No. of rooms 2.336 0.925 1 7
Monthly fees 3,234.237 1,198.525 932 8,011
Distance to CBD 47.761 536.312 0.314 6,765.676
Distance to subway 42.411 524.241 0.002 6,609.22
No. of building floors 3.953 2.337 0 14
Elevator 0.653 0.476 0 1
New 0.019 0.137 0 1
Age 60.006 38.005 −2 1,000
Gentrification income 0.184 0.388 0 1
Gentrification population 0.169 0.375 0 1
Distance to gentrification income 1,326.452 1,359.982 0 4,999.634
Distance to gentrification population 1,485.097 1,509.16 0 7,142.767
Notes:

The number of observations is 25,898; prices are in Swedish Krona (SEK) and distance is in metres

Regression results (default models 2014–2015)

Variables (1) (2) (3) (4)
M1 M1 M3 M4
Gentrification income 0.0597*** (18.48) 0.0231*** (5.64)
Gentrification population 0.0792*** (22.83) 0.0638*** (14.46)
Gentrification income and population 0.0779*** (20.60)
New 0.134*** (15.85) 0.133*** (15.86) 0.135*** (16.03) 0.130*** (15.46)
Age 0.000560*** (14.62) 0.000556*** (14.61) 0.000569*** (14.93) 0.000529*** (13.88)
Elevator 0.0318*** (10.37) 0.0320*** (10.48) 0.0324*** (10.63) 0.0325*** (10.62)
Floor level 0.0196*** (25.11) 0.0193*** (24.91) 0.0195*** (25.09) 0.0194*** (24.98)
Building stories 0.000962 (1.58) 0.000745 (1.23) 0.000909 (1.50) 0.000921 (1.51)
Living area 0.0132*** (104.04) 0.0133*** (104.65) 0.0133*** (104.77) 0.0132*** (104.24)
Distance to CBD −0.0754*** (−116.74) −0.0725*** (−112.38) −0.0733*** (−111.16) −0.0735*** (−114.38)
Distance subway station 0.0771*** (116.72) 0.0742*** (112.34) 0.0750*** (111.13) 0.0752*** (114.34)
Rooms 0.0383*** (13.98) 0.0378*** (13.87) 0.0380*** (13.92) 0.0377*** (13.80)
Monthly fee −0.0000689*** (−39.54) −0.0000682*** (−39.36) −0.0000686*** (−39.58) −0.0000675*** (−38.88)
Constant 14.47*** (2255.28) 14.47*** (2261.91) 14.46*** (2259.32) 14.47*** (2261.97)
Observations 23,017 23,017 23,017 23,017
R2 0.843 0.844 0.844 0.843
AIC −16,115.3 −16,291.7 −16,321.5 −16,196.8
Notes:

t statistics in parentheses. ***p < 0.001

Spillover effect models

Variables (1) (2) (3) (4)
M5 M6 M7 M8
Gentrification income 0.0618*** (17.87) 0.0333*** (7.65)
Distance gentrification income 0.00000179 (1.70) 0.0000126*** (8.66) 0.0000102*** (7.41)
Gentrification population 0.0724*** (20.24) 0.0521*** (11.53)
Distance gentrification population −0.00000740*** (−7.58) −0.0000151*** (−11.15) −0.0000156*** (−11.77)
Gentrification income and population 0.0736*** (19.07)
New 0.133*** (15.82) 0.134*** (15.94) 0.134*** (15.97) 0.129*** (15.43)
Age 0.000553*** (14.34) 0.000575*** (15.10) 0.000554*** (14.47) 0.000524*** (13.67)
Elevator 0.0314*** (10.23) 0.0349*** (11.36) 0.0358*** (11.67) 0.0364*** (11.85)
Floor level 0.0196*** (25.13) 0.0194*** (25.00) 0.0196*** (25.35) 0.0195*** (25.18)
Building stories 0.000897 (1.47) 0.000864 (1.42) 0.000660 (1.09) 0.000719 (1.18)
Living area 0.0132*** (103.61) 0.0133*** (105.01) 0.0132*** (104.50) 0.0132*** (104.22)
Distance to CBD −0.0757*** (−113.56) −0.0726*** (−112.60) −0.0752*** (−108.14) −0.0747*** (−112.75)
Distance subway station 0.0774*** (113.54) 0.0742*** (112.55) 0.0769*** (108.11) 0.0764*** (112.71)
Rooms 0.0383*** (13.99) 0.0380*** (13.95) 0.0385*** (14.15) 0.0382*** (14.01)
Monthly fee −0.0000686*** (−39.21) −0.0000691*** (−39.82) −0.0000684*** (−39.37) −0.0000677*** (−38.86)
Constant 14.47*** (2226.80) 14.47*** (2234.03) 14.47*** (2229.51) 14.48*** (2241.20)
Observations 23,017 23,017 23,017 23,017
R2 0.843 0.844 0.845 0.844
AIC −16,116.2 −16,347.2 −16,443.4 −16,331.7
Notes:

t statistics in parentheses. ***p < 0.001

Treatment effect model (reduced sample and propensity score weights)

Variables (1) (2) (3) (4)
TE1 PS1 TE2 PS2
Gentrification income 0.0329*** (8.41) 0.0252*** (6.13)
Gentrification population 0.0306*** (7.43) 0.0105* (2.30)
New 0.111*** (7.11) 0.115*** (6.53) 0.0708*** (4.26) 0.0891*** (5.16)
Age 0.000133 (1.79) −0.0000729*** (−7.83) 0.0000325 (0.39) −0.0000596*** (−5.16)
Elevator 0.0407*** (7.82) 0.0248*** (4.63) 0.0360*** (6.52) 0.0233*** (4.09)
Floor level 0.0225*** (16.66) 0.0238*** (16.32) 0.0212*** (14.00) 0.0227*** (13.09)
Building stories −0.000677 (−0.65) −0.00122 (−1.12) −0.00422*** (−3.51) −0.00639*** (−4.70)
Living area 0.0116*** (48.53) 0.0122*** (35.96) 0.0119*** (47.31) 0.0125*** (28.58)
Distance to CBD −0.0779*** (−63.81) −0.0810*** (−60.81) −0.103*** (−67.81) −0.111*** (−65.16)
Distance subway station 0.0797*** (63.80) 0.0828*** (60.81) 0.105*** (67.80) 0.113*** (65.15)
Rooms 0.0514*** (10.99) 0.0382*** (6.44) 0.0502*** (10.31) 0.0278*** (3.80)
Monthly fee −0.0000573*** (−18.55) −0.0000573*** (−13.85) −0.0000555*** (−17.10) −0.0000529*** (−12.50)
Constant 14.49*** (1,270.52) 14.53*** (1,839.65) 14.56*** (1,117.27) 14.61*** (1,384.68)
Observations 8,023 8,023 7,018 7,018
R2 0.786 0.818 0.792 0.830
AIC −6,041.2 −9,774.9 −5,652.6 −17,453.8
Notes:

t statistics in parentheses. *p < 0.05, **p < 0.01, ***p < 0.001

Quantile regression results, treatment effect model

Quantiles Gentrification income Gentrification population
0.1 0.0471*** 0.0463***
0.2 0.0314*** 0.0400***
0.3 0.0260*** 0.0365***
0.4 0.0213*** 0.0275***
0.5 0.0277*** 0.0348***
0.6 0.0276*** 0.0347***
0.7 0.0284*** 0.0308***
0.8 0.0248*** 0.0268***
0.9 0.0235*** 0.0153*
Notes:

*p < 0.05, ***p < 0.001

Note

References

Amédée-Manesme, C.O., Baroni, M., Barthélémy, F. and Des Rosiers, F. (2016), “Market heterogeneity and the determinants of Paris apartment prices: a quantile regression approach”, Urban Studies, Vol. 54 No. 14, pp. 1-21.

Atkinson, R. (2004), “The evidence on the impact of gentrification: new lessons for the urban renaissance?”, European Journal of Housing Policy, Vol. 4 No. 1, pp. 107-131.

Barton, M. (2016), “An exploration of the importance of the strategy used to identify gentrification”, Urban Studies, Vol. 53 No. 1, pp. 92-111.

Braswell, T.H. (2018), “Fresh food, new faces: community gardening as ecological gentrification in St. Louis, Missouri”, Agriculture and Human Values, Vol. 35 No. 4, pp. 809-822.

Chum, A. (2015), “The impact of gentrification on residential evictions”, Urban Geography, Vol. 36 No. 7, pp. 1083-1098.

Ding, L., Hwang, J. and Divringi, E. (2016), “Gentrification and residential mobility in Philadelphia”, Regional Science and Urban Economics, Vol. 61, pp. 38-51.

Easton, S., Lees, L., Hubbard, P. and Tate, N. (2020), “Measuring and mapping displacement: the problem of quantification in the battle against gentrification”, Urban Studies, Vol. 57 No. 2, pp. 286-306.

Ellen, I.G. and O'Regan, K.M. (2008), “Reversal of fortunes? Lower-income urban neighborhoods in the US in the 1990s”, Urban Studies, Vol. 45 No. 4, pp. 845-869.

Ellen, I.G. and O'Regan, K.M. (2011), “How low income neighborhoods change: entry, exit, and enhancement”, Regional Science and Urban Economics, Vol. 41 No. 2, pp. 89-97.

Glass, R. (1964), Aspects of Change, No. 3, MacGibbon & Kee, London.

Guerrieri, V., Hartley, D. and Hurst, E. (2013), “Endogenous gentrification and housing price dynamics”, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 100, pp. 45-60.

Hackworth, J. and Smith, N. (2001), “The changing state of gentrification”, Tijdschrift Voor Economische en Sociale Geografie, Vol. 92 No. 4, pp. 464-477.

He, S. (2007), “State-sponsored gentrification under market transition the case of Shanghai”, Urban Affairs Review, Vol. 43 No. 2, pp. 171-198.

Hedin, K., Clark, E., Lundholm, E. and Malmberg, G. (2012), “Neoliberalization of housing in Sweden: gentrification, filtering, and social polarisation”, Annals of the Association of American Geographers, Vol. 102 No. 2, pp. 443-463.

Hwang, J. and Sampson, R.J. (2014), “Divergent pathways of gentrification: racial inequality and the social order of renewal in Chicago neighborhoods”, American Sociological Review, Vol. 79 No. 4, pp. 726-751.

Ilic, L., Sawada, M. and Zarzelli, A. (2019), “Deep mapping gentrification in a large Canadian city using deep learning and Google street view”, PloS One, Vol. 14 No. 3, p. e0212814.

Immergluck, D. (2009), “Large redevelopment initiatives, housing values and gentrification: the case of the Atlanta beltline”, Urban Studies, Vol. 46 No. 8, pp. 1723-1745.

Kennedy, M. and Leonard, P. (2001), Dealing with Neighborhood Change: A Primer on Gentrification Policy Choices, Brookings Institution Center on Urban and Metropolitan Policy, Washington, DC.

Koenker, R. and Bassett, G. Jr, (1978), “Regression quantiles”, Econometrica, Vol. 46 No. 1, pp. 33-50.

Kolko, J. (2007), “The determinants of gentrification”, Available at SSRN ID=985714.

Kostov, P. (2009), “A spatial quantile regression hedonic model of agricultural land prices”, Spatial Economic Analysis, Vol. 4 No. 1, pp. 53-72.

Lees, L., Slater, T. and Wyly, E. (2008), Gentrification, Routledge, London.

Ley, D. (1986), “Alternative explanations for inner-city gentrification: a Canadian assessment”, Annals of the Association of American Geographers, Vol. 76 No. 4, pp. 521-535.

Ley, D., Tutchener, J. and Cunningham, G. (2002), “Immigration, polarisation, or gentrification? Accounting for changing house prices and dwelling values in gateway cities”, Urban Geography, Vol. 23 No. 8, pp. 703-727.

Liao, W.C. and Wang, X. (2012), “Hedonic house prices and spatial quantile regression”, Journal of Housing Economics, Vol. 21 No. 1, pp. 16-27.

López-Morales, E. (2016), “Gentrification in Santiago, Chile: a property-led process of dispossession and exclusion”, Urban Geography, Vol. 37 No. 8, pp. 1109-1131.

McKinnish, T., Walsh, R. and White, T.K. (2010), “Who gentrifies low-income neighborhoods?”, Journal of Urban Economics, Vol. 67 No. 2, pp. 180-193.

McMillen, D. (2008), “Changes in the distribution of house prices over time: structural characteristics, neighborhood, or coefficients?”, Journal of Urban Economics, Vol. 64 No. 3, pp. 573-589.

Marcuse, P. (1985), “Gentrification, abandonment, and displacement: connections, causes, and policy responses in New York city”, Urban Law Annual; Journal of Urban and Contemporary Law, Vol. 28 No. 1, p. 195.

Murdie, R. and Teixeira, C. (2011), “The impact of gentrification on ethnic neighborhoods in Toronto: a case study of little Portugal”, Urban Studies, Vol. 48 No. 1, pp. 61-83.

Ord, J.K. and Getis, A. (1995), “Local spatial autocorrelation statistics: distributional issues and an application”, Geographical Analysis, Vol. 27 No. 4, pp. 286-306.

Podagrosi, A., Vojnovic, I. and Pigozzi, B. (2011), “The diversity of gentrification in Houston's urban renaissance: from cleansing the urban poor to supergentrification”, Environment and Planning A: Economy and Space, Vol. 43 No. 8, pp. 1910-1929.

Rérat, P., Söderström, O., Piguet, E. and Besson, R. (2010), “From urban wastelands to new‐build gentrification: the case of Swiss cities”, Population, Space and Place, Vol. 16 No. 5, pp. 429-442.

Rosen, S. (1974), “Hedonic prices and implicit markets: product differentiation in pure competition”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 82 No. 1, pp. 34-55.

Scott, A.J. (2019), “Residential adjustment and gentrification in Los Angeles, 2000–2015 theoretical arguments and empirical evidence”, Urban Geography, Vol. 40 No. 4, pp. 506-528.

Shaw, K. (2010), “Teaching and learning guide for gentrification: what it is, why it is, and what can be done about it”, Geography Compass, Vol. 4 No. 4, pp. 383-387.

Shaw, W.S. (2000), “Ways of whiteness: Harlemising Sydney's aboriginal redfern”, Australian Geographical Studies, Vol. 38 No. 3, pp. 291-305.

Smith, N. (1996), The New Urban Frontier: Gentrification and the Revanchist City, Psychology Press.

Smith, N. (2002), “New globalism, new urbanism: gentrification as global urban strategy”, Antipode, Vol. 34 No. 3, pp. 427-450.

Songchitruksa, P. and Zeng, X. (2010), “Getis–ord spatial statistics to identify hot spots by using incident management data”, Transportation Research Record: Journal of the Transportation Research Board, Vol. 2165 No. 1, pp. 42-51.

Walks, A., Hawes, E. and Simone, D. (2021), “Gentrification in large Canadian cities: tenure, age, and exclusionary displacement 1991-2011”, Urban Geography, pp. 1-31.

Waltl, S. (2016), “Variation across price segments and locations: a comprehensive quantile regression analysis of the Sydney housing market”, Real Estate Economics, Vol. 47 No. 3, pp. 1-34.

Wyly, E.K. and Hammel, D.J. (1999), “Islands of decay in seas of renewal: housing policy and the resurgence of gentrification”, Housing Policy Debate, Vol. 10 No. 4, pp. 711-777.

Yoo, J. and Frederick, T. (2017), “The varying impact of land subsidence and earth fissures on residential property values in Maricopa county – a quantile regression approach”, International Journal of Urban Sciences, Vol. 21 No. 2, pp. 204-216.

Zhang, H. and Wang, X. (2016), “Effectiveness of macro-regulation policies on housing prices: a spatial quantile regression approach”, Housing, Theory and Society, Vol. 33 No. 1, pp. 23-40.

Zhang, L. (2016), “Flood hazards impact on neighborhood house prices: a spatial quantile regression analysis”, Regional Science and Urban Economics, Vol. 60, pp. 12-19.

Zietz, J., Zietz, E.N. and Sirmans, G.S. (2008), “Determinants of house prices: a quantile regression approach”, The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, Vol. 37 No. 4, pp. 317-333.

Acknowledgements

The autors thank the research project Housing 2.0 (Bostad 2.0) for financial support and Mäklarstatistik AB for data.

Corresponding author

Mats Wilhelmsson can be contacted at: mats.wilhelmsson@abe.kth.se

Related articles