Abstract
Purpose
The purpose of this paper is to use tenets of the complexity theory in order to study the effect of various determinants of firm’s performance, such as CEO’s compensation and age, for the case of 72 insurance companies.
Design/methodology/approach
The authors identify the asymmetries in the data set by creating quantiles and using contrarian analysis. Instead of ignoring this information and use a main effects approach, all the available information in the data set is taken into account. For this purpose, the authors use qualitative comparative analysis to find alternative equifinal routes toward high firm performance.
Findings
Five configurations are found which lead to high performance. Every one of the five configurations is found to be sufficient but not necessary for high firm performance.
Originality/value
The research findings contribute to a better understanding of the determinants of firm’s performance taking into account the asymmetries in the data set. The authors identify alternative paths toward high firm performance, which could be vital information for the decision maker inside a firm.
Keywords
Citation
Kourtzidis, S. and Tzeremes, N.G. (2020), "Investigating the determinants of firm performance: A qualitative comparative analysis of insurance companies", European Journal of Management and Business Economics, Vol. 29 No. 1, pp. 3-22. https://doi.org/10.1108/EJMBE-09-2018-0094
Publisher
:Emerald Publishing Limited
Copyright © 2019, Stavros Kourtzidis and Nickolaos G. Tzeremes
License
Published in European Journal of Management and Business Economics. Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode
1. Introduction
The performance of a firm is affected by a variety of factors including organizational aspects such as the size, the history and the structure of the firm; environmental aspects such as socio-economic background and technological framework; and human aspects such as individual characteristics, motivation and skills. There is a debate across the literature about the effect of human factor on firm’s performance, especially the effect of top managers. The neoclassical economic theory considers top managers as homogenous and perfect substitutes with each other (Bertrand and Schoar, 2003), while the managerial talent hypothesis indicates that managers affect the performance of the firm (Hubbard and Palia, 1995). The top ranked manager of the firm is the chief executive officer (CEO) or managing director who is responsible for the firm’ overall operations and performance. According to managerial talent hypothesis, the effect of the CEO’s individual performance should greatly influence the performance of the firm.
The scientific interest focuses on the specific factors and characteristics of CEOs which affect the firm. Motivation is considered among the most important factors, with compensation[1] and bonuses as its key determinants (Cashman, 2010; Livne et al., 2011). In addition, based on the principal-agent theory the principal (board of directors) decides the optimal level and composition of the agent’s (CEO) compensation in order to better align their interest. Therefore, total compensation (compensation and bonuses) provide motivation and align the CEO’s interests with the interests of the firm. Furthermore, the CEO’s characteristics, such as age (Sturman, 2003) and tenure (Mousa and Chowdhury, 2014), also influence his decisions and, consequently, the performance of the firm. The decremental theory of aging suggests that older individuals tend to have declining physical and mental skills (Giniger et al., 1983). Nevertheless, older individuals tend to be more experienced which is important for complex jobs such as CEO.
The majority of the previous literature regarding the CEO characteristics and firm performance focus on non-financial sector. The relationship between CEO pay and performance is at the center of this literature and the argument is that shareholders’ interests and managers’ interests are better aligned when CEO compensation is connected with shareholders’ gains and losses. However, this relationship has been questioned in the financial sector, especially in the aftermath of the global financial crisis. Specifically, the argument is about CEO incentives and whether or not they are aligned with shareholders’ and firm’s interests (Fahlenbrach and Stulz, 2011). Furthermore, CEOs in banks receive lower compensation and fewer incentives, while the pay–performance relationship is more sensitive (Houston and James, 1995). Therefore, it is important to examine the effect of CEO pay on firm performance in the financial sector.
In line with the above, this study focuses on the effect of various determinants of financial firm’s performance, including the CEO’s total compensation and age, the size and the age of the firm. Specifically, we examine the case of seventy-two insurance companies. The contribution lies both in the empirical literature of CEO compensation in general and the key factors of firm performance in financial sector in particular. Although a great variety of studies focus on the effect of CEO compensation on firm performance and a number of studies on the effect of other factors such as firm size and CEO age, only a few of them explore this link in financial sector. Furthermore, this is the first study to explore all these factors simultaneously, which allows us to take a broader look regarding the performance of a firm.
The vast majority of previous studies applies multiple regression analysis (MRA) in order to examine firm performance and its determinants, therefore assuming a linear relationship (Sun et al., 2013; Sheikh et al., 2018). Another strand in the literature argues that this relationship is non-linear and found various types of asymmetries (Fong et al., 2015; Matousek and Tzeremes, 2016). This study uses the complexity theory tenets in order to examine possible asymmetrical relationships between antecedents (CEO’s compensation and age among others) and the outcome condition (firm’s performance). These tenets suggest equifinality, which implies that more than one path can lead to the desired outcome (Wu et al., 2014). Furthermore, this study applies contrarian case analysis by creating quantiles in order to shed further light on the asymmetrical relationship among the variables. Moreover, configural analysis is applied, which uses Boolean algebra in order to find which combinations of simple antecedents lead to a high outcome condition. In addition, we perform a predictive validity test using a holdout sample in order to check the validity of our findings.
The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the current literature about the relationship among the firm’s performance and its various determinants, which include CEO’s compensation and age, the size and the age of the firm. Section 3 presents the description of the variables used, the contrarian analysis and the outline of the configural analysis. The results of the approach are presented in Section 4, and Section 5 concludes.
2. Theory and hypothesis
2.1 Review of the recent literature
The previous empirical literature mainly focuses on the effect of CEO compensation on industrial firm performance. The results indicate a positive relationship, however, the exact nature of this relationship has caused some debate whether the effect is high, moderate or low, and also if high compensation leads to high performance or the opposite, therefore, if the relationship is symmetrical or asymmetrical. Hall and Liebman (1998) studied the case of publicly traded US companies and found a significant relationship among pay and performance, and they rejected the hypothesis that CEOs are paid as bureaucrats. The case of 455 US firms for the time period 1996–2002 was studied by Nourayi and Daroca (2008). The authors examined the relationship among the CEO’s cash and total compensation, and the firm’s size and performance. The results showed a small positive but significant relationship among compensation and performance. Ghosh (2010) examined the case of 324 Indian manufacturing firms for the year 2007 and found a small positive but significant relationship among CEO pay and firm performance. Raithatha and Komera (2016) investigated the linear relationship among firm performance and executive compensation in India and found a positive relationship between accounting performance and compensation; however, this finding is not verified for the case of stock market performance. Similarly, Sheikh et al. (2018) examined the linear relationship among firm performance, executive compensation and corporate governance in Pakistan, and verified the positive relationship between accounting performance and compensation, and no relationship between stock market performance and compensation.
On the other hand, a number of studies found evidence of non-linear relationship between firm performance and CEO compensation. The practical limits of incentive pay were highlighted by Mishra et al. (2000) who investigated 430 firms over the period 1974-1988. The findings indicated a non-linear relationship among the CEO’s pay and firm performance. Specifically, increasing pay sensitivity results in higher firm performance up to a certain point, beyond which the results turn to be negative. Nourayi and Mintz (2008) examined the pay–performance relationship for 1,446 firms for the years 2001 and 2002. The results revealed that compensation of inexperienced CEOs with under three years in the office was related to firm performance, while there was no relationship for more experienced CEOs. Bulan et al. (2010) investigated 917 manufacturing firms for the time period 1992–2003 and found a non-linear relationship between CEO pay incentives and firm productivity. The findings revealed that pay incentives do not always achieve their purpose and excessive incentives might lead to opposite results. In fact, it is quite possible that in the absence of a supervisory board, the CEO will manipulate the firm’s strategy in order to achieve higher compensation. Fong et al. (2015) found a non-linear relationship among the CEO’s compensation and long-term firm’s market value for 582 non-financial non-utility US firms for the time period 1991–1999. Specifically, the relationship was initially positive up to a threshold, and beyond that point the relationship became negative. Furthermore, there are studies which link low firm performance with CEO turnover, even if the low performance is due to factors beyond the control of the CEO (Jenter and Kanaan, 2015; Bennett et al., 2017).
A number of studies across the literature focus on the financial sector. Crawford et al. (1995) found a strong positive relationship between bank performance and incentives for CEO’s compensation and wealth (salary, bonus, stock options and common stock holdings) in the post-deregulation period. Hubbard and Palia (1995) confirmed the positive pay–performance relationship for the case where the interstate banking is permitted. Houston and James (1995) examined CEOs in 134 commercial banks and 134 non-banking firms and found that there are structural differences among CEOs in banks and CEOs in non-banking firms in terms of their compensation. Specifically, the results reveal that CEOs in banks receive lower compensation and fewer incentives, while the pay–performance relationship is more sensitive in banks. Ang et al. (2002) investigated CEOs and non-CEO top executives in 166 US banks and found that the pay–performance relationship is positive and significant for CEOs. Cũnat and Guadalupe (2009) examined banking and financial sectors and demonstrated that increased competition and deregulation increased the pay–performance sensitivity. John et al. (2010) studied CEOs in 143 bank holding companies and found that the link between compensation and performance lessens with the leverage ratio and strengthens with outside monitoring. Sun et al. (2013) tested the relationship among CEO compensation and firm performance, measured by efficiency, in the US property-liability insurance industry for the time period 2000–2006. The findings revealed that revenue efficiency was related to cash compensation, and cost efficiency was related to incentive compensation.
On the other hand, a negative or non-linear relationship between firm performance in financial sector and CEO compensation was reported by a number of studies. Barro and Barro (1990) were among the first to study the connection of CEO compensation and firm performance in financial sector. They examined the total compensation (salary and bonus) of CEOs in large commercial banks. The results revealed a positive relationship between total compensation and the firm’s performance; however, more experienced CEOs were affected less by compensation changes. Livne et al. (2011) studied 152 firms (mainly commercial banks) for the time period 1996–2008. The authors found that cash bonus and firm performance were positively related, while equity-based compensation was negatively related with firm performance. Matousek and Tzeremes (2016) examined the effect of CEO compensation on the bank efficiency levels and found a significant non-linear relationship among them. Furthermore, the results indicated than CEO salary and bonus affected differently the level of the efficiency. In summary, we expect the effect of the CEO’s compensation on firm performance to be substantial and positive at the beginning, with a diminishing rate for higher levels.
There is also a strand in the literature which explores the link between various types of compensation structures and risk taking, which indirectly affects firm performance; however, the results do not indicate a clear relationship among them. Specifically, Chen et al. (2006) investigated commercial banks during the time period 1992–2000 and found that after deregulation the CEO compensation was significantly based on stock options. As a result, the authors noted that the structure of CEO compensation encourage risk taking. Bebchuk et al. (2010) and Bhagat and Bolton (2014) examined the case of financial institutions and found that managerial incentive pay matters. Furthermore, they recommend the use of restricted stocks and restricted stock options in order to handle the induced risk taking, while Bolton et al. (2015) suggested to link credit default swaps with compensation in order to tackle the issue. Gande and Kalpathy (2017) examined large US firms before crisis and found that equity incentives, which were tied to the CEO compensation resulted in risk taking and solvency problems. At the same time, higher incentive alignment moderated the problems. On the other hand, Houston and James (1995) found no evidence that bank CEO compensation induces risk taking. This result is confirmed by Acrey et al. (2011) for the case of the largest US banks, that is, CEO compensation is either insignificantly or negatively correlated with common risk variables. In a similar framework, Bai and Elyasiani (2013) investigated the link between CEO compensation and bank stability, and found a bi-directional relationship among them. King et al. (2016) found that management education allows the CEOs to better manage risk-taking activities and innovative business models in order to achieve higher firm performance.
The CEO’s individual characteristics could also have a significant effect on financial firm’s performance. Specifically, the CEO’s age could be an important factor; however, the effect is not clear and the results are mixed. On the one hand, older CEOs are more experienced, and, on the other hand, their physical and mental skills are naturally declining (Giniger et al., 1983) and also they are reluctant to risk, which could lead to missed opportunities and lower firm performance. Based on these contradictory effects, Sturman (2003) hypothesized that the relationship between age and performance is non-linear (U-shaped). The results did not support his hypothesis about a U-shaped relationship; however, the nature of the relationship was indeed non-linear and significant. Mishra et al. (2000) confirmed that age affects CEO’s motivation. Specifically, they found that younger CEOs tend to take more risks than older CEOs. McClelland et al. (2012) extends this rationale by arguing that older CEOs have shorter career horizons than younger CEOs, which lead them toward more risk-averse decisions and consequently to the firm’s lower performance. Nguyen et al. (2018) investigated Australian firms for the time period 2001–2011 and found that CEO age is a significant and negatively related factor for firm performance, meaning that younger CEOs achieve better results than older CEOs. Therefore, we build on the premise that younger CEOs are more motivated than older CEOs, which led them to achieve higher firm performance. However, we expect this relationship to be non-linear due to the essential experience of older CEOs.
Based on the above analysis, we can summarize that many scholars found a positive relationship among CEO compensation and firm performance which is either non-linear or significant only for younger CEOs (Barro and Barro, 1990; Mishra et al., 2000; Nourayi and Mintz, 2008; Fong et al., 2015). Therefore, we would expect that high compensation would lead to high firm performance in a configuration which a younger CEO is present:
High CEO compensation for a younger CEO lead to high firm performance.
Firm size is a contingent factor and lies within the contingency theory framework of organizational design (Donaldson, 2006). The number of employees and total assets in a firm are indications of its size. Large firms differ structurally from small ones in a variety of terms such as rules and regulations, manager levels, budget and scale of operation. Chow and Fung (1997) examined manufacturing enterprises in Shanghai and found that larger firms achieve better performance. Lundvall and Battese (2000) investigated Kenyan manufacturing firms in four sectors and the results revealed that firm size is a significant indicator of performance for two sectors. Diaz and Sanchez (2008) analyzed the case of Spanish manufacturing firms and verified the significant positive relationship among firm size and performance. Chandran and Rasiah (2013) found evidence that firm size affects various aspects of firm’s operational activities, such as its performance. Evidently, we expect that larger firms which have a better position in the market would achieve better performance than smaller firms. In financial literature, firm size is considered as an important factor to control the pay–performance sensitivity. John and Qian (2003) hypothesized that larger firms should have lower sensitivity regarding the pay–performance relationship and confirmed the hypothesis for the banking industry. Furthermore, Hubbard and Palia (1995), Bliss and Rosen (2001) and Ang et al. (2002) found a significant connection among bank size and CEO compensation.
Based on the above, we would expect large size in terms of assets and employees to be present in most of the configurations:
Large-sized firms achieve high firm performance.
Another contingent factor is the age of the firm. Throughout different life stages firms evolve in terms of systems, procedures and regulations. Firms in the youth stage tend to be innovative and flexible, they are willing to take higher risks, they expand and hire, and, ultimately, they are pursuing higher growth. They are in the process to adopt and develop a framework for rules and regulations and distinguish levels of management. Firms in the maturity stage have all the above in place, have an established place in the market and significant experience in their field. On the one hand, some empirical studies show mixed results regarding how the age of firm affects firm performance (Lundvall and Battese, 2000; Söderbom and Teal, 2004). Giachetti (2012) argued that the experience is a significant factor of firm’s performance. On the other hand, another strand in the literature argues that newer firms focus more on innovation, which leads them to perform better (Hansen, 1992; Balasubramanian and Lee, 2008). In line with these findings, Moreno and Castillo (2011) found an inverse relationship between age and firm’s growth.
It has been reported that younger CEOs tend to take more risks than older CEOs and they also tend to be more innovative (Mishra et al., 2000). Furthermore, newer firms focus more on innovation which leads them to perform better (Hansen, 1992; Balasubramanian and Lee, 2008). Therefore, we would expect that a younger CEO will lead to high firm performance in a newer firm. On the other hand, an older CEO, who is more experienced and risk-averse, will be expected to achieve better results in an older firm where the experience is a significant factor of firm’s performance (Giachetti, 2012):
Younger CEO in a newer firm leads to high firm performance.
Older CEO in an older firm leads to high firm performance.
3. Methodology
MRA treats firm’s performance as the dependent variable (Y) and the CEO’s total compensation and age as the independent variables (X), along with other determinants of the firm’s performance. MRA assesses if the effect of a single independent variable (e.g. the CEO’s compensation) on firm’s performance is significant (and positive or negative) after separating it from the effect of other independent variables (net effect). Such analysis investigates a symmetrical relationship among dependent and independent variables; high values of X associate with high values of Y and low values of X associate with low values of Y. On the contrary, asymmetrical techniques allow a number of values of X to have a counter effect than the observed net effect; for example, high values of X may associate with high values of Y, but low values of X could also associate with high values of Y (Woodside, 2013). Asymmetrical relationships are undoubtedly more often in real data set than symmetrical ones (Woodside, 2014).
3.1 Variable description and data
In this study, we investigate the determinants of the performance of insurance companies with special focus on the effect of the CEO’s total compensation and age. Throughout the literature, it is a common practice to use sales as a measure of the firm’s performance (Anthony et al., 1992; Feltham and Xie, 1994). Cook and Hababou (2001) marked the intensification of the financial services industry and the significant role of sales as a measure of their performance. In this study, we choose sales (in billion dollars) as a proxy for the performance of the insurance companies and use it as the outcome condition.
The data sample contains the top 72 insurance companies from around the world. The data set was manually extracted from multiple sources; the Forbes Global 2000[2] database, Datastream, Bloomberg and salaries.com[3]. Forbes Global 2000 is an annual ranking for the top 2,000 public companies in the world published by Forbes magazine. From the top 2,000 companies, we selected the 72 diversified insurance and life and health insurance companies. Table AI contains information about the companies in our group: the country of origin, the name of the CEO and the date they were founded. Apart from the CEO’s total compensation and age, we also use additional determinants for firm performance. We use firm’s assets (in billion dollars) and labor (measured as the number of employees) as measures of firm’s size and key aspects of the production process. In addition, we use the number of years since the insurance company was founded as a measure of firm’s seniority. The reference year for all variables is 2013. Table I presents the descriptive statistics of the variables used in the analysis, and Table II demonstrates the correlations of the variables used. The correlation matrix shows that some variables are related, while others are not related. Therefore, the symmetrical correlation test (Pearson’s correlation) yields mixed results, however we suspect that our set contains asymmetrical data. In the next section, we search for these asymmetries.
3.2 Cross-tabulation
This section presents a variable by variable analysis and searches for contrarian cases in the data. We construct the cross between sales (which is the outcome variable) and every one of the simple antecedent variables[4]. All the variables have been divided into quantiles (Woodside, 2014); the first 20 percent of the observations are “very low,” 20–40 percent are “low,” 40–60 percent are “medium,” 60–80 percent are “high” and 80–100 percent are “very high.” Table III presents the cross of sales and total compensation. Each cell contains the number of observed cases; for example, the very low sales and very low compensation takes place five times. The percentage under the observed cases is the percentage within the row; 33 percent of the cases with very low compensation have very low sales. Furthermore, there are two rounded rectangles in every table. The one on the upper right-hand side shows the negative contrarian cases; the cases where the compensation is low and the sales are high. The other one on the lower left-hand side shows the positive contrarian cases; the cases where the compensation is high and the sales are low. In Table III, there are nine negative and eight positive contrarian cases. Furthermore, Somer’s d is provided in every table. This statistic is an asymmetrical test and it is used for the measurement of the association between two ordinal variables. In Table III, Somer’s d reveals that there is a significant association between sales and compensation[5].
Regarding the overall results of sales vs every other variable, there are 33 negative and 29 positive contrarian cases. Somer’s d shows that every variable, except the CEO’s age, has significant association with sales. The small Somer’s d for age indicates a small effect size, however we observe that contrarian cases are still present. The only combination of variables which has no contrarian cases is sales-assets. Rather than using symmetrical approaches which consider only positive or negative cases, we use fuzzy-set qualitative comparative analysis (QCA) which considers both positive and negative routes of the antecedents in order to reach a high outcome condition (Wu et al., 2014).
3.3 Qualitative comparative analysis (QCA)
This paper employs QCA, which is a set-theoretic approach that uses Boolean algebra to investigate the relationships among the outcome condition and every possible combination of binary states (membership and non-membership) of the antecedent conditions (Longest and Vaisey, 2008). Since our variables are continuous, they need to be calibrated for the needs of the approach. QCA is naturally based on dichotomous variables with two states, membership and non-membership. Fuzzy sets allow the calibrated variables to range from 0 (non-membership) to 1 (full membership) with intermediate thresholds (Ragin, 2000). The procedure of the calibration is analogous to z-scale transformation. According to Woodside (2013) the three breakpoints that need to be specified are: the original value covering the 5 percent of the data set which is the threshold for non-membership; the original value covering the 50 percent of the data set which is the median threshold for membership/non-membership; and the original value covering the 95 percent of the data set which is the threshold for full membership. Following Woodside (2013) and Beraha et al. (2018), this paper uses the fsQCA software for the calibration of the original variables into fuzzy sets[6].
After the calibration procedure, fsQCA uses every possible combination of simple and complex antecedent conditions to find every possible route toward a high outcome condition. A complex condition in Boolean algebra is made using the logical statement “and” which is equal to the lowest value of the simple antecedents which are used, and it is denoted as “•” (Woodside, 2014). For example, suppose the simple antecedents A, B and C which have already been calibrated into fuzzy sets and their values are 0.08, 0.60 and 0.45, respectively. The complex antecedent A•B•C means that all three simple antecedents must be present simultaneously and the value of the complex antecedent is 0.08. Furthermore, the symbol “~” means not present. For example, ~A means A is not present and its value is 1−A=0.92 (Woodside, 2013). Having established the above, we can define the property space of QCA, which includes every possible combination of antecedents (present and absent) toward the outcome condition (Ordanini et al., 2014). Since there are five simple antecedent conditions in this study, the number of every possible combination of them is 25=32. Table IV presents the property space.
Two very important indices for QCA are consistency and coverage. Consistency measures the sufficiency of the configurations (see Table IV) for the outcome condition (sales in this case). Essentially, consistency indicates the degree to which membership in each solution term is a subset of the outcome condition and it is considered as analogous to a correlation index in statistical approaches (Wu et al., 2014). It is calculated as:
4. Empirical findings
4.1 Test for fit validity
This section conducts QCA using the fsQCA computer software. Following Ragin (2008b), we have captured over 80 percent of the cases by setting a frequency threshold of 2.00 and also adapted consistencies over 0.75 (specifically the smallest consistency is about 0.85). Table V presents the results. Each of the five rows shows a complex antecedent condition which is sufficient for achieving high firm performance. The five configurations explain about 80 percent high firm performance in our sample (total coverage=0.803) and the overall consistency is high (0.8875). The complex antecedents are explained as follows:
This complex configuration, which is the final antecedent in Table V, means that a path for achieving high firm performance is a younger CEO with high compensation and a large-size firm (indicated by high assets), which is in the market for many years. At first, none of the simple antecedent conditions are present in every complex solution, which implies that none of them is necessary for achieving high firm performance. However, we can see that high assets and high number of employees, which are both indicators of a large size firm, are present in four of the five solutions. Furthermore, the five different equifinal routes reveal that although every single one configuration is sufficient for high firm performance, none of them is necessary. Regarding the five sufficient configurations, the fourth (high CEO compensation, high assets and high employees) achieves the highest level of unique coverage (0.0897) meaning that it is the path which explains the largest share of the outcome variable. The complex antecedent which follows is the fifth solution (high CEO compensation, a younger CEO and a large-size firm with many years since established) with unique coverage of 0.0425. This path explains the second largest share of firm performance.
An overall examination of the results confirms H1 – that a high CEO compensation for younger CEOs affects firm performance – since it is present in the second solutions with the highest unique coverage. This finding verifies the results of Barro and Barro (1990), who found a positive relationship between total compensation and firm’s performance; however, more experienced CEOs were affected less by compensation changes. H2, about the size of the firm, is validated in every configuration, since a larger size either in terms of assets or employees is present in every configuration, which is in line with the previous literature (Chow and Fung, 1997; Lundvall and Battese, 2000; Diaz and Sanchez, 2008). Furthermore, the results are contradictory regarding H3. Specifically, H3a – younger CEOs in newer firms achieve better firm performance – is verified in the first solution in Table V. This confirms the results of Nguyen et al. (2018) and is in line with the argument of Mishra et al. (2000) about the CEO’s age and motivation. However, H3b – older CEOs in older firms achieve better firm performance – is not verified. In fact, the last solution in Table V shows that younger CEOs can achieve high firm performance in older and larger firms.
The results provide valuable insights for the decision maker. First, a higher compensation seems to lead to high firm performance in the case of larger firms. Furthermore, larger firms in terms of assets and number of employees achieve better firm performance with a younger and more motivated CEO. Last, investment in expanding the firm in terms of either assets and/or number of employees should lead to higher firm performance in most of the cases.
4.2 Robustness check
This section conducts QCA but, instead of using sales, it used stock returns as a measure of firm performance. Core et al. (2006) and Li et al. (2015) argued that accounting-based variables are better proxies for firm performance and that it is a common practice for credit-rating agencies and banks. Furthermore, managers are often evaluated in terms of accounting-based indicators of firm performance. Furthermore, it can be argued that market-based indicators do not reflect the current firm performance, which can be addressed as an inverse cycle of production. An accounting-based indicator solves this issue. Various accounting-based indicators have been used across the literature such as return on assets (Matolcsy and Wright, 2011), return on equity (Li et al., 2015), shareholder return (Ozkan, 2011). In this section, we follow Brick et al. (2006), Core et al. (2006) and Larcker et al. (2007), and use stock returns as a measure of firm performance.
Table VI presents the results. In this case, we have captured only the 66.6 percent of the cases by setting a frequency threshold of 2.00 and consistencies over 0.75. The coverage is smaller than the case of sales because there are more cases here with consistencies below the threshold of 0.75. Each of the five rows in Table VI show a complex antecedent condition which is sufficient for achieving high firm performance. The five configurations explain about 66.6 percent high firm performance in our sample (total coverage=0.666) and the overall consistency is 0.687.
First, none of the simple antecedent conditions are present in every complex solution, which implies that none of them is necessary for achieving high firm performance. Furthermore, the five different equifinal routes reveal that although every single one configuration is sufficient for high firm performance, none of them is necessary. Regarding the five sufficient configurations, the first (high CEO age, low assets, low employees and high number of years) achieves the highest level of unique coverage (0.145326), meaning that it is the path which more frequently leads to high firm performance. This solution means that there is a path for small firms (in terms of assets and number of employees) to achieve high firm performance, and that is if they have an older and more experienced CEO and they are in market for a long time period. The complex antecedent which follows is the second solution (high CEO compensation, a younger CEO and a large-size firm) with a unique coverage of 0.055732.
An overall examination of the results reveals that the new outcome variable does not contradict but at the same time does not reinforce previous results. Specifically, this confirms H1 since it is present in the second and the third solutions in Table VI, which is in line with our previous findings. In contrast with the case of sales, we find evidence supporting the H3b but no evidence about H3a. Specifically, the first solution in Table VI, which is the solution with the higher unique coverage, supports that older CEOs in older firms achieve higher firm performance, even if the firm is small in size. There is also the fourth solution where younger CEOs achieve high firm performance in older and larger firms, but this solution has a significantly lower unique coverage than the previously mentioned. Last, H3 is verified in all but the first solution.
Although there are various paths to firm performance, we can detect a pattern. A more experienced CEO seems to be a better solution for smaller firms while bigger firms should invest in younger more motivated CEOs which is contradicting with our hypotheses. A high CEO compensation and a long time period in the market seem to be good choices toward high firm performance since they are present in most of the solutions.
A comparison between the stock returns model in this section and the sales model in the previous section reveals that the later has a better fit in modelling terms. However, in terms of interpretation, they yield similar results. First, both of them support a higher CEO compensation toward high firm performance. Second, there is a solution (the best solution) in the case of stock returns which is different but not contradicting with the case of sales. This solution shows that smaller firms have indeed a path toward high firm performance. Apart from that solution, both of the models find that a younger CEO is preferred for larger firms and that a longer time period in the market is a good element for success.
4.3 Test for predictive validity
Figure 1 presents the XY plot of fourth and fifth configurations in Table V and the outcome condition (firm performance). Each dot represents one or more firms since two or more firms may achieve the same score. Figure 1(a) represents the configuration with the highest unique coverage and Figure 1(b) the configuration with the second highest unique coverage. The XY plots of remaining three configurations and firm performance are similar with either Figure 1(a) or (b). Every XY plot in our study reveals that the relationships are indeed asymmetrical. For example, Figure 1(a) indicates that high values of the complex antecedent lead to high values of firm performance; however, low values of antecedent lead to both high and low values of firm performance. Therefore, high values of X are sufficient for high firm performance but not necessary, since low values of X could also lead to high firm performance (Woodside, 2013). This is a strong indication of an asymmetrical relationship. This finding could be associated with the results of Sturman (2003), Bulan et al. (2010) and Fong et al. (2015), who found that the CEO’s compensation and age have a non-linear relationship with firm performance. This valuable information would have been taken into consideration if we had used regression analysis or other symmetrical approaches.
According to Gigerenzer and Brighton (2009), it is important to test not only for fit validity but also for predictive validity. Following Wu et al. (2014), we split our sample into two subsamples. We use the first as a modeling subsample and the second as a holdout subsample. Table VII presents the results of the modeling subsample where the second configuration:
5. Conclusions
In this study, we have used tenets of the complexity theory, in order to study the effect of CEO’s compensation and age on the firm’s performance. Instead of using MRA or other symmetrical approaches, we identified the asymmetries in the data set using contrarian analysis. The results reveal the presence of both positive and negative contrarian cases. Rather than ignoring this valuable information and use a main effects approach, we chose to exploit all the available information in the data set. For this purpose, we used QCA to find alternative equifinal routes toward high firm performance.
The empirical findings revealed five configurations which can lead to high firm performance. The configuration which leads to higher performance more often found to be the one with high CEO’s compensation and a large-sized firm (a firm with both high assets and high number of employees). Furthermore, we confirmed that no single antecedent condition leads to high firm performance and there is a need for complex antecedents (which are consisted by simple antecedents). Also, the results showed that every single one of the final five configurations is sufficient for achieving high firm performance; however, none of them is necessary, since the high outcome could be achieved with alternative configurations, even if they are less frequently used by the firms. Finally, we tested for predictive validity using a modeling and a holdout subsample.
The results reveal that the CEO’s high compensation relates to high firm performance, especially for younger CEOs, which is in line with the findings of previous studies (Barro and Barro, 1990). Furthermore, larger firms in terms of assets and number of employees, achieve better firm performance with a younger and more motivated CEO. On the other hand, a more experienced CEO appears as a better solution for smaller firms. Last, investment in the size of the firm, either in terms of assets or number of employees, leads to high firm performance, which confirms the findings of Chow and Fung (1997), Diaz and Sanchez (2008) and Lundvall and Battese (2000). The results of robustness check, where stock returns replace sales as the outcome condition, verify our findings. Specifically, there is strong evidence regarding the hypothesis that high compensation for a younger CEO lead to high firm performance.
The results provide useful policy implications for the interested groups (among others shareholders, CEOs, investors). Achieving high firm performance is multi-dimensional in nature and cannot be achieved by focusing only on a single element (e.g. CEO compensation). Also, there is no perfect “recipe” toward high firm performance. On the other hand, there are multiple alternative routes that a firm can follow to achieve high firm performance, as long as it adopts the correct strategy mix.
5.1 Limitations
This section presents the limitations of our analysis. First, the reference year for our data set is 2013. The data were manually collected and some data were only available for a year. If more years were available, it would be very interesting to examine lagged models. Specifically, we could analyze the impact of lags in configuration on outcome predictive accuracy. We believe that such an analysis would add great depth to our model and also valuable insights for the decision maker.
Furthermore, there is a limitation regarding the use of market-based indicators as a measure of firm performance. We have addressed this issue in Section 4.2. Specifically, we argued that accounting-based variables may prove to be better proxies for firm performance. In this essence, we used stock returns as a measure of firm performance to perform a robustness check of our results.
Figures
Descriptive statistics of the variables
Min. | Max. | Mean | SD | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Sales (B$) | 1 | 138.9 | 25.71 | 29.99 |
Total compensation ($) | 65,178 | 7,651,345 | 2,024,571 | 1,730,414 |
Age (years) | 45 | 79 | 57.5 | 6.84 |
Assets (B$) | 15 | 1,488.7 | 215.6 | 283.6 |
Number of employees | 226 | 203,366 | 23,642 | 35,587 |
Operating years | 12 | 231 | 91.4 | 56.88 |
Correlation matrix for the variables used
Sales | Compensation | Age | Assets | Employees | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Compensation | 0.433* (0.000) | ||||
Age | 0.017 (0.889) | 0.066 (0.581) | |||
Assets | 0.773* (0.000) | 0.310* (0.008) | −0.050 (0.679) | ||
Employees | 0.730* (0.000) | 0.164 (0.169) | 0.011 (0.927) | 0.670* (0.000) | |
Years | 0.255** (0.030) | 0.266** (0.024) | 0.058 (0.629) | 0.133 (0.266) | −0.030 (0.800) |
Notes: *,**Significant at 0.01 and 0.05 levels, respectively
Cross-tab of CEO’s compensation and firm’s sales
![]() |
Configurations of binary states of antecedents that could influence firm performance
Antecedents | No. of cases | % of total space |
---|---|---|
~Compensation•~age•~assets•~employees•~year | 7 | 9.72 |
~Compensation•age•~assets•~employees•~year | 7 | 9.72 |
~Compensation•age•~assets•~employees•year | 4 | 5.56 |
Compensation•age•assets•employees•year | 4 | 5.56 |
Compensation•~age•assets•employees•year | 5 | 6.94 |
Compensation•age•~assets•~employees•year | 3 | 4.17 |
Compensation•~age•assets•~employees•year | 5 | 6.94 |
~Compensation•age•assets•employees•~year | 3 | 4.17 |
~Compensation•~age•assets•employees•~year | 4 | 5.56 |
Compensation•age•assets•employees•~year | 3 | 4.17 |
Compensation•age•~assets•~employees•~year | 2 | 2.78 |
Compensation•~age•assets•employees•~year | 3 | 4.17 |
Compensation•~age•~assets•employees•~year | 2 | 2.78 |
Compensation•~age•~assets•~employees•~year | 2 | 2.78 |
~Compensation•~age•assets•employees•year | 3 | 4.17 |
~Compensation•~age•~assets•employees•~year | 2 | 2.78 |
Compensation•age•assets•~employees•~year | 1 | 1.39 |
Compensation•~age•~assets•employees•year | 1 | 1.39 |
Compensation•~age•~assets•~employees•year | 2 | 2.78 |
~Compensation•age•assets•employees•year | 1 | 1.39 |
~Compensation•age•assets•~employees•year | 1 | 1.39 |
~Compensation•age•~assets•employees•year | 1 | 1.39 |
~Compensation•age•~assets•employees•~year | 1 | 1.39 |
~Compensation•~age•assets•~employees•~year | 1 | 1.39 |
~Compensation•~age•~assets•employees•year | 1 | 1.39 |
~Compensation•~age•~assets•~employees•year | 1 | 1.39 |
Compensation•age•assets•~employees•year | 1 | 1.39 |
Compensation•age•~assets•employees•year | 1 | 1.39 |
Compensation•age•~assets•employees•~year | 0 | 0.00 |
Compensation•~age•assets•~employees•~year | 0 | 0.00 |
~Compensation•age•assets•~employees•~year | 0 | 0.00 |
~Compensation•~age•assets•~employees•year | 0 | 0.00 |
Total | 72 | 100.00 |
Configurations predicting high firm performance
Raw coverage | Unique coverage | Consistency | |
---|---|---|---|
~Age*employees*~year | 0.42 | 0.03 | 0.87 |
Assets*employees*~year | 0.47 | 0.04 | 0.98 |
~Age*assets*employees | 0.55 | 0.01 | 0.98 |
Compensation*assets*employees | 0.61 | 0.09 | 1.00 |
Compensation*~age*assets*year | 0.43 | 0.04 | 0.92 |
Complex solution | |||
Frequency cutoff: 2.00 | |||
Consistency cutoff: 0.858746 | |||
Solution coverage: 0.803021 | |||
Solution consistency: 0.887564 |
Configurations predicting high firm performance: robustness check
Raw coverage | Unique coverage | Consistency | |
---|---|---|---|
Age*~assets*~employees*year | 0.41 | 0.15 | 0.75 |
Compensation*~age*assets*employees | 0.42 | 0.06 | 0.79 |
Compensation*~age*assets*years | 0.39 | 0.02 | 0.77 |
~Age*assets*employees*year | 0.37 | 0.01 | 0.78 |
Compensation*assets*employees*year | 0.42 | 0.04 | 0.76 |
Complex solution | |||
Frequency cutoff: 2.00 | |||
Consistency cutoff: 0.751767 | |||
Solution coverage: 0.666314 | |||
Solution consistency: 0.687159 |
Configurations predicting high firm performance for the modeling subsample
Raw coverage | Unique coverage | Consistency | |
---|---|---|---|
~Compensation*employees*~year | 0.40 | 0.04 | 0.92 |
Compensation*assets*employees | 0.65 | 0.19 | 1.00 |
~Compensation*~age*assets*~year | 0.35 | 0.05 | 0.97 |
~Compensation*age*~assets*employees | 0.27 | 0.01 | 0.93 |
Compensation*~age*employees*~year | 0.39 | 0.01 | 0.95 |
Complex solution | |||
Frequency cutoff: 1.00 | |||
Consistency cutoff: 0.905297 | |||
Solution coverage: 0.8208833 | |||
Solution consistency: 0.0.941458 |
Companies information
Company | Country of Origin | CEO name | Founded |
---|---|---|---|
Allianz | Germany | Michael Diekmann | 1890 |
AXA Group | France | Henri De Castries | 1852 |
American International Group | USA | Robert Benmosche | 1919 |
Ping An Insurance Group | China | Mingzhe Ma | 1988 |
MetLife | USA | Steven Kandarian | 1999 |
Zurich Insurance Group | Switzerland | Martin Senn | 1872 |
Munich Re | Germany | Nikolaus von Bomhard | 1880 |
Generali Group | Italy | Mario Greco | 1831 |
Swiss Re | Switzerland | Michael Lies | 1863 |
Allstate | USA | Thomas Wilson | 1931 |
ACE | Switzerland | Evan Greenberg | 1985 |
Aegon | Netherlands | Alex Wynaendts | 1969 |
CNP Assurances | France | Frederic Lavenir | 1959 |
Mapfre | Spain | Antonio Huertas Mejias | 1933 |
Talanx | Germany | Herbert Haas | 1903 |
Sampo | Finland | Kari Henrik Stadigh | 1909 |
Loews | USA | James Tisch | 1904 |
Ageas | Belgium | Bart De Smet | 1824 |
Suncorp Group | Australia | Patrick J Snowball | 1902 |
Hartford Financial Services | USA | Liam McGee | 1985 |
XL Group | Bermuda | Michael Mcgavick | 1986 |
Scor | France | Denis Kessler | 1855 |
Bâloise Group | Switzerland | Martin Strobel | 1864 |
Vienna Insurance Group | Austria | Peter Hagen | 1898 |
Unipol Gruppo | Italy | Carlo Cimbri | 1961 |
Everest Re Group | Bermuda | Joseph Taranto | 1993 |
Reinsurance Group of America | USA | Albert Greig Woodring | 1992 |
Assurant | USA | Robert Pollock | 1969 |
Helvetia Holding | Switzerland | Stefan Loacker | 1996 |
Ambac Financial Group | USA | Diana Adams | 1971 |
Storebrand | Norway | Odd Arild Grefstad | 1982 |
Uniqa | Austria | Andreas Brandsetter | 1922 |
Delta Lloyd | Netherlands | Niek Hoek | 1807 |
PartnerRe | Bermuda | Constantinos Miranthis | 1993 |
American Financial Group | USA | Carl Lindner III | 1872 |
Direct Line Insurance | UK | Paul Geddes | 1985 |
Cincinnati Financial | USA | Steven Johnston | 1950 |
Axis Capital Holdings | Bermuda | Albert Benchimol | 2001 |
Markel | USA | Alan Kirshner | 1930 |
Assured Guaranty | Bermuda | Dominic Frederico | 1988 |
E-L Financial | Canada | Duncan N R Jackman | 1968 |
Cattolica Assicurazioni | Italy | Giovan Battista Mazzucchelli | 1896 |
Erie Indemnity | USA | Terrence Cavanaugh | 1925 |
American Natl Ins | USA | Robert Moody | 1905 |
China Life Insurance | China | Feng Wan | 1949 |
ING Group | Netherlands | Ralph Hamers | 1991 |
Prudential | UK | Tidjane Thiam | 1848 |
Aviva | UK | Mark Wilson | 1908 |
AIA Group | Hong Kong | Mark Tucker | 1919 |
Manulife Financial | Canada | Donald Guloien | 1887 |
Aflac | USA | Daniel Amos | 1955 |
Legal & General Group | UK | Nigel Wilson | 1836 |
China Pacific Insurance | China | Guo fo Gao | 1991 |
Sun Life Financial | Canada | Dean Connor | 1865 |
Power Corp of Canada | Canada | Paul Desmarais Jr | 1925 |
Standard Life | UK | David Nish | 1825 |
Lincoln National | USA | Dennis Glass | 1904 |
Prudential Financial | USA | John Strangfeld Jr | 1875 |
Principal Financial Group | USA | Larry Zimpleman | 1879 |
Unum Group | USA | Thomas Watjen | 1848 |
Sanlam | South Africa | Johan van Zyl | 1918 |
Mediolanum | Italy | Ennio Doris | 1995 |
Phoenix Group Holdings | UK | Clive C Bannister | 1782 |
Industrial Alliance Insurance | Canada | Yvon Charest | 1905 |
Torchmark | USA | Larry Hutchison | 1900 |
CNO Financial Group | USA | Edward Bonach | 1979 |
MMI Holdings | South Africa | Nicolaas Kruger | 1989 |
American Equity Investment | USA | John Matovina | 1995 |
Symetra Financial | USA | Thomas Marra | 1957 |
Notes
CEOs’ compensation has attracted the research interest regarding many aspects of a firm, for example, risk exposure (Fahlenbrach and Stulz, 2011), regulation/deregulation (Cũnat and Guadalupe, 2009), and mergers and acquisitions (Kroll et al., 1990).
Independent variable.
The other four tables with the crosstabs of sales and each one of the remaining four antecedents (age, assets, number of employees and years since establishment) are available upon request.
For a detailed explanation of the calibration technique, see Ragin (2008a).
Appendix
References
Acrey, J.C., McCumber, W.R. and Nguyen, T.H.T. (2011), “CEO incentives and bank risk”, Journal of Economics and Business, Vol. 63 No. 5, pp. 456-471.
Ang, J., Lauterbach, B. and Schreiber, B.Z. (2002), “Pay at the executive suite: how do US banks compensate their top management teams?”, Journal of Banking Finance, Vol. 26 No. 6, pp. 1143-1163.
Anthony, R.N., Dearden, J. and Govindarajan, V. (1992), Management Control Systems, Irwin, Boston, MA.
Bai, G. and Elyasiani, E. (2013), “Bank stability and managerial compensation”, Journal of Banking Finance, Vol. 37 No. 3, pp. 799-813.
Balasubramanian, N. and Lee, J. (2008), “Firm age and innovation”, Industrial and Corporate Change, Vol. 17 No. 5, pp. 1019-1047.
Barro, J.R. and Barro, R.J. (1990), “Pay, performance, and turnover of bank CEOs”, Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 8 No. 4, pp. 448-481.
Bebchuk, L., Cohen, A. and Spamann, H. (2010), “The wages of failure: executive compensation at Bear Stearns and Lehman 2000–2008”, Yale Journal on Regulation, Vol. 27 No. 2, pp. 257-282.
Bennett, B., Bettis, J.C., Gopalan, R. and Milbourn, T. (2017), “Compensation goals and firm performance”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 124 No. 2, pp. 307-330.
Beraha, A., Bingol, D., Ozkan-Canbolat, E. and Szczygiel, N. (2018), “The effect of strategic flexibility configurations on product innovation”, European Journal of Management and Business Economics, Vol. 27 No. 2, pp. 129-140.
Bertrand, M. and Schoar, A. (2003), “Managing with style: the effect of managers on firm policies”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 118 No. 4, pp. 1169-1208.
Bhagat, S. and Bolton, B. (2014), “Financial crisis and bank executive incentive compensation”, Journal of Corporate Finance, Vol. 25, April, pp. 313-341.
Bliss, R.T. and Rosen, R.J. (2001), “CEO compensation and bank mergers”, Journal of Finance Economics, Vol. 61 No. 1, pp. 107-138.
Bolton, P., Mehran, H. and Shapiro, J. (2015), “Executive compensation and risk taking”, Review of Finance, Vol. 19 No. 6, pp. 2139-2181.
Brick, I.E., Palmon, O. and Wald, J.K. (2006), “CEO compensation, director compensation, and firm performance: evidence of cronyism?”, Journal of Corporate Finance, Vol. 12 No. 3, pp. 403-423.
Bulan, L., Sanyal, P. and Yan, Z. (2010), “A few bad apples: an analysis of CEO performance pay and firm productivity”, Journal of Economics and Business, Vol. 62 No. 4, pp. 273-306.
Cashman, G.D. (2010), “Pay-performance sensitivity and firm size: insights from the mutual fund industry”, Journal of Corporate Finance, Vol. 16 No. 4, pp. 400-412.
Chandran, V.G.R. and Rasiah, R. (2013), “Firm size, technological capability, exports and economic performance: the case of electronics industry in Malaysia”, Journal of Business Economics and Management, Vol. 14 No. 4, pp. 741-757.
Chen, C.R., Steiner, T.L. and Whyte, A.M. (2006), “Does stock option-based executive compensation induce risk-taking? An analysis of the banking industry”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 30 No. 3, pp. 915-945.
Chow, C.K.W. and Fung, M.K.Y. (1997), “Firm size and performance of manufacturing enterprises in P.R. China: the case of Shanghai’s manufacturing industries”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 9 No. 3, pp. 287-298.
Cook, W.D. and Hababou, M. (2001), “Sales performance measurement in bank branches”, Omega, Vol. 29 No. 4, pp. 299-307.
Core, J., Guay, W. and Rusticus, T. (2006), “Does weak governance cause weak stock returns? An examination of firm operating performance and investors’ expectations”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 61 No. 2, pp. 655-687.
Crawford, A.J., Ezzell, J.R. and Miles, J.A. (1995), “Bank CEO pay-performance relations and the effects of deregulation”, Journal of Business, Vol. 68 No. 2, pp. 231-256.
Cũnat, V. and Guadalupe, M. (2009), “Executive compensation and competition in the banking and financial sectors”, Journal of Banking Finance, Vol. 33 No. 3, pp. 495-504.
Diaz, M.A. and Sanchez, R. (2008), “Firm size and productivity in Spain: a stochastic frontier analysis”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 30 No. 3, pp. 315-323.
Donaldson, L. (2006), “The contingency theory of organizational design: challenges and opportunities”, in Burton, R.M., Eriksen, B., Hakonsson, D.D. and Snow, C.C. (Eds), Organization Design: The Evolving State-Of-Art, Springer Science + Business Media, New York, NY, pp. 19-40.
Fahlenbrach, R. and Stulz, R.M. (2011), “Bank CEO incentives and the credit crisis”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 99 No. 1, pp. 11-26.
Feltham, G.A. and Xie, J. (1994), “Performance measure congruity and diversity in multi-task principal/agent relations”, Accounting Review, Vol. 69 No. 3, pp. 429-453.
Fong, E.A., Xing, X., Orman, W.H. and Mackenzie, W.I. Jr (2015), “Consequences of deviating from predicted CEO labor market compensation on long-term firm value”, Journal of Business Research, Vol. 68 No. 2, pp. 299-305.
Gande, A. and Kalpathy, S. (2017), “CEO compensation and risk-taking at financial firms: evidence from U.S. federal loan assistance”, Journal of Corporate Finance, Vol. 47, December, pp. 131-150.
Ghosh, S. (2010), “Firm performance and CEO pay: evidence from Indian manufacturing”, Journal of Entrepreneurship, Vol. 19 No. 2, pp. 137-147.
Giachetti, C. (2012), “A resource-based perspective on the relationship between service diversification and firm performance: evidence from Italian facility management firms”, Journal of Business Economics and Management, Vol. 13 No. 3, pp. 567-585.
Gigerenzer, G. and Brighton, H. (2009), “Homo heuristicus: why biased minds make better inferences”, Topics in Cognitive Science, Vol. 1 No. 1, pp. 107-143.
Giniger, S., Dispenzieri, A. and Eisenberg, J. (1983), “Age, experience, and performance on speed and skill jobs in applied setting”, Journal of Applied Psychology, Vol. 68 No. 3, pp. 469-475.
Hall, B.J. and Liebman, J.B. (1998), “Are CEOs really paid like bureaucrats?”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 113 No. 3, pp. 653-691.
Hansen, J.A. (1992), “Innovation, firm size, and firm age”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 4 No. 1, pp. 37-44.
Houston, J.F. and James, C. (1995), “CEO compensation and bank risk: is compensation in banking structured to promote risk taking?”, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 36 No. 2, pp. 405-431.
Hubbard, R.G. and Palia, D. (1995), “Executive pay and performance: evidence from the U.S. banking industry”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 39 No. 1, pp. 105-130.
Jenter, D. and Kanaan, F. (2015), “CEO turnover and relative performance evaluation”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 70 No. 5, pp. 2155-2184.
John, K. and Qian, Y. (2003), “Incentive features in CEO compensation in the banking industry”, Economic Policy Review, Vol. 9 No. 1, pp. 109-121.
John, K., Mehran, H. and Qian, Y. (2010), “Outside monitoring and CEO compensation in the banking industry”, Journal of Corporate Finance, Vol. 16 No. 4, pp. 383-399.
King, T., Srivastav, A. and Williams, J. (2016), “What’s in an education? Implications of CEO education for bank performance”, Journal of Corporate Finance, Vol. 37, April, pp. 287-308.
Kroll, M., Simmons, S.A. and Wright, P. (1990), “Determinants of chief executive officer compensation following major acquisitions”, Journal of Business Research, Vol. 20 No. 4, pp. 349-366.
Larcker, D.F., Richardson, S.A. and Tuna, I. (2007), “Corporate governance, accounting outcomes, and organizational performance”, The Accounting Review, Vol. 82 No. 4, pp. 963-1008.
Li, M.-Y.L., Yang, T.-H. and Yu, S.-E. (2015), “CEO stock-based incentive compensation and firm performance: a quantile regression approach”, Journal of International Financial Management & Accounting, Vol. 26 No. 1, pp. 39-71.
Livne, G., Markarian, G. and Milne, A. (2011), “Bankers’ compensation and fair value accounting”, Journal of Corporate Finance, Vol. 17 No. 4, pp. 1096-1115.
Longest, K. and Vaisey, S. (2008), “Fuzzy: a program for performing qualitative comparative analysis (QCA) in STATA”, STATA Journal, Vol. 8 No. 1, pp. 79-104.
Lundvall, K. and Battese, G.E. (2000), “Firm size, age and efficiency: evidence from Kenyan manufacturing firms”, The Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 36 No. 3, pp. 146-163.
McClelland, P.L., Barker, V.L. III and Oh, W.-Y. (2012), “CEO carrier horizon and tenure: future performance implications under different contingencies”, Journal of Business Research, Vol. 65 No. 9, pp. 1387-1393.
Matolcsy, Z. and Wright, A. (2011), “CEO compensation structure and firm performance”, Accounting & Finance, Vol. 51 No. 3, pp. 745-763.
Matousek, R. and Tzeremes, N.G. (2016), “CEO compensation and bank efficiency: an application of conditional nonparametric frontiers”, European Journal of Operational Research, Vol. 251 No. 1, pp. 264-273.
Mishra, C.S., McConaughy, D.L. and Gobeli, D.H. (2000), “Effectiveness of CEO pay-for-performance”, Review of Financial Economics, Vol. 9 No. 1, pp. 1-13.
Moreno, J.J. and Castillo, L.L. (2011), “Corporate growth, age and ownership structure: empirical evidence in Spanish firms”, Journal of Business Economics and Management, Vol. 12 No. 1, pp. 164-196.
Mousa, F.-T. and Chowdhury, J. (2014), “Organizational slack effects on innovation: the moderating roles of CEO tenure and compensation”, Journal of Business Economics and Management, Vol. 15 No. 2, pp. 369-383.
Nguyen, P., Rahman, N. and Zhao, R. (2018), “CEO characteristics and firm valuation: a quantile regression analysis”, Journal of Management & Governance, Vol. 22 No. 1, pp. 133-151.
Nourayi, M.M. and Daroca, F.P. (2008), “CEO compensation, firm performance and operational characteristics”, Managerial Finance, Vol. 34 No. 8, pp. 562-584.
Nourayi, M.M. and Mintz, S.M. (2008), “Tenure, firm’s performance, and CEO’s compensation”, Managerial Finance, Vol. 34 No. 8, pp. 524-536.
Ordanini, A., Parasuraman, A. and Rubera, G. (2014), “When the recipe is more important that the ingredients: a qualitative comparative analysis (QCA) of service innovation configurations”, Journal of Service Research, Vol. 17 No. 2, pp. 134-149.
Ozkan, N. (2011), “CEO compensation and firm performance: an empirical investigation of UK panel data”, European Financial Management, Vol. 17 No. 2, pp. 260-285.
Ragin, C. (2000), Fuzzy-Set Social Science, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL.
Ragin, C. (2008a), Redesigning Social Inquiry: Fuzzy Sets and Beyond, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL.
Ragin, C. (2008b), User’s Guide to Fuzzy Set/Qualitative Comparative Analysis, Department of Sociology, University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ.
Raithatha, M. and Komera, S. (2016), “Executive compensation and firm performance: evidence from Indian firms”, IIMB Management Review, Vol. 28 No. 3, pp. 160-169.
Sheikh, M.F., Shah, S.Z.A. and Akbar, S. (2018), “Firm performance, corporate governance and executive compensation in Pakistan”, Applied Economics, Vol. 50 No. 18, pp. 2012-2027.
Söderbom, M. and Teal, F. (2004), “Size and efficiency in African manufacturing firms: evidence from firm-level panel data”, Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 73 No. 1, pp. 369-394.
Sturman, M.C. (2003), “Searching for the inverted U-shaped relationship between time and performance: meta-analyses of the experience/performance, tenure/performance, and age/performance relationships”, Journal of Management, Vol. 29 No. 5, pp. 609-640.
Sun, F., Wei, X. and Huang, X. (2013), “CEO compensation and firm performance: evidence from the US property and liability insurance industry”, Review of Accounting and Finance, Vol. 12 No. 3, pp. 252-267.
Woodside, A.G. (2013), “Moving beyond multiple regression analysis to algorithms: calling for adoption of a paradigm shift from symmetric to asymmetric thinking in data analysis and crafting theory”, Journal of Business Research, Vol. 66 No. 4, pp. 463-472.
Woodside, A.G. (2014), “Embrace•perform•model: complexity theory, contrarian case analysis, and multiple realities”, Journal of Business Research, Vol. 67 No. 12, pp. 2495-2503.
Wu, P.-L., Yeh, S.-S., Huan, T.C. and Woodside, A.G. (2014), “Applying complexity theory to deepen service dominant logic: configural analysis of customer experience-and-outcome assessment of professional services for personal transformations”, Journal of Business Research, Vol. 67 No. 8, pp. 1647-1670.