Abstract
Purpose
The purpose of our study is to investigate the effects of politically-connected boards (PCBs) on over-(under-)investment in labor. We also examine the impacts of the supervisory board (SB)’s optimal tenure on the association between PCBs and over-investment in labor.
Design/methodology/approach
We constructed the proxy for PCBs using a dummy variable set to 1 (one) if a firm has politically-connected boards and zero (0) otherwise. For the robustness check, we used the number of politically-connected members on the boards as the proxy for PCBs.
Findings
We find that the presence of PCBs reduces over-investment in labor. Consistent with our prediction, we found no significant association between PCBs and under-investment in labor. We also find that the SB with optimal tenure strengthens the negative association between PCBs and over-investment in labor. In our channel analysis, we find that the presence of PCB mitigates over-investment in labor through a higher dividend payout ratio.
Research limitations/implications
Due to the unavailability of data in firms’ annual reports regarding the number of poorly-skilled and highly skilled employees, we were not able to examine the effect of low-skilled and high-skilled employees on over-investment in labor. Also, we were not able to examine over-(under-)investment in labor by drawing a distinction between general (generalist) and firm-specific human capital (specialist) as suggested by Sevcenko, Wu, and Kacperczyk (2022). Generally, it is more difficult for managers to hire highly-skilled employees, specialists in particular, thereby driving the choice of either over- or under-investing in the labor forces. In addition, in the firms’ annual reports, there is no information regarding temporary employees. Therefore, if and when such data become available, this would provide another avenue for future research.
Practical implications
Our study offers several practical implications and insights to stakeholders (e.g. insiders or management, shareholders, investors, analysts and creditors) in the following ways. First, our study highlights significant differences between capital investment and labor investment. For instance, labor investment is considered an expense rather than an asset (Wyatt, 2008) because, although such investment is human capital and is not recognized on the firm’s balance sheet (Boon et al., 2017). In addition, labor investment is characterized by: its flexibility which enables firms to make frequent adjustments (Hamermesh, 1995; Dixit & Pindyck, 2012; Aksin et al., 2015), its non-homogeneity since every employee is unique (Luo et al., 2020), its direct impact on morale and productivity of a firm (Azadegan et al., 2013; Mishina et al., 2004; Tatikonda et al., 2013), and its financial outlay which affects the ongoing cash flows of a firm (Sualihu et al., 2021; Khedmati et al., 2020; Merz & Yashiv, 2007). Second, our findings reveal that the presence of PCBs could help to reduce over-investment in labor. However, if managers of a firm choose to under-invest in labor in order to obtain better profit in the short-term through cost saving, they should be aware of the potential consequences of facing a financial loss when a new business opportunity suddenly arises which requires a larger labor force. Third, our findings help stakeholders to re-focus on the labor investment. This is crucial due to the fact that labor investment is often neglected by those stakeholders because the expenditure of labor investment is not recognized on the firm’s balance sheet as an asset. Instead, it is written off as an expense in the firm’s income statement. Fourth, our findings also provide insightful information to stakeholders, suggesting that an SB with optimal tenure is more committed to a firm, and this factor plays an important role in strengthening the negative association between PCBs and over-investment in labor.
Social implications
First, our findings provide a valuable understanding of the effects of PCBs on over-(under-)investment in labor. Stakeholders could use information disclosed in the financial statements of a publicly-listed firm to determine the extent of the firm’s investment in labor and PCBs, and compare this information with similar firms in the same industry sector. Second, our findings give a better understanding of the association between investment in labor and political connections , which are human and social capital that could determine the long-term survival and success of a firm. Third, for shareholders, the appointment of board members with political connections is an important strategic decision to build political capital, which is likely to have a long-term impact on the financial performance of a firm; therefore, it requires thoughtful consultation with firm insiders.
Originality/value
Our findings highlight the role of PCBs in reducing over-investment in labor. These findings are significant because both investment in labor and political connections as human and social capital can play an important role in determining the long-term survival and success of a firm.
Keywords
Citation
Harianto, S. and Haman, J. (2024), "The effects of political connections on labor investment: evidence from Indonesia", China Accounting and Finance Review, Vol. 26 No. 5, pp. 565-598. https://doi.org/10.1108/CAFR-11-2023-0145
Publisher
:Emerald Publishing Limited
Copyright © 2024, Sandy Harianto and Janto Haman
License
Published in China Accounting and Finance Review. Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode
1. Introduction
Human capital plays an important role in contributing to the financial performance of a firm and the economic growth of a country. Firms with effective management of human resources related to labor investment in particular are generally in a better position to compete and prosper in a changing market environment [1]. Drábek, Lorincová, and Javorčíková (2017) assert that the future will certainly belong to firms which focus on investing in human capital. As a country that has strong growth opportunities (World Economics, 2024), Indonesia offers businesses and investors a lucrative opportunity for market expansion, which may affect labor investment. By capitalizing on the potential for business expansion, political connections could offer firms a number of sources of information including the government’s medium- and long-term economic policy and strategy (González-Bailon, Jennings, & Lodge, 2013; Liu, Xin, & Li, 2021). This may help managers to predict market demands more accurately, thereby reducing over-invesment in labor. Since political connections require commitment from top management, and to maximize the benefits of such political connections, shareholders may strategically appoint former public officials and politicians with established reputations as stewards to their boards [2].
Prior studies have investigated how labor investment efficiency is associated with various firm characteristics such as financial reporting quality (Jung, Lee, & Weber, 2014), equity-based compensation (Sualihu, Rankin, & Haman, 2021), CEO-director ties (Khedmati, Sualihu, & Yawson, 2020), employee-friendly treatment (Cao & Rees, 2020), and prospector(defender-)type business strategy (Habib & Hasan, 2021). Furthermore, prior studies have examined the impacts of political connections on the capital investment efficiency. They find that political connections increase the inefficiency of capital investment (Chen, Sun, Tang, & Wu, 2011; Duchin & Sosyura, 2012; Cherkasova & Ivanova, 2019). What is missing from the landscape of prior studies (Jung et al., 2014; Khedmati et al., 2020; Cao & Rees, 2020; Habib & Hasan, 2021; Chen, Sun, et al., 2011; Duchin & Sosyura, 2012; Cherkasova & Ivanova, 2019) is an investigation to determine whether political connections influence labor investment. Our study addresses this gap by examining the impacts of politically-connected boards (PCBs) on over-(under-)investment in labor. This is important because the findings of prior studies (Chen, Sun, et al., 2011; Duchin & Sosyura, 2012; Cherkasova & Ivanova, 2019) on the association between political connections and capital investment inefficiency cannot be meaningfully extrapolated to investment in labor for the following reasons.
Firstly, investment in labor differs from investment in capital expenditures. Unlike the latter (e.g. plant, property and equipment/PPE), which refers to tangible assets that are listed on a firm’s balance sheet, the expenditure related to investment in labor is not capitalized; instead, it is written off as an expense in the firm’s income statement (Wyatt, 2008). Because it is considered an expense, managers and other stakeholders (e.g. shareholders, investors, analysts and creditors) often pay less attention to investment in labor. It is worth noting that investment in labor should not be seen merely in terms of a firm’s financial outlay, but as the most important off-balance-sheet asset, which comprises human capital characterized by a pool of skills, knowledge, talents and capabilities that could generate greater net economic benefits than those of a firm’s competitors (Boon, Eckardt, Lepak, & Boselie, 2017).
Secondly, unlike capital investment, costs related to labor investment (e.g. salary, wages and related expenses) affect a firm’s cash flow on an ongoing basis (Sualihu et al., 2021; Khedmati et al., 2020; Merz & Yashiv, 2007). Further, capital investment such as PPE is homogenous. Conversely, the labor force is not homogenous since every employee is unique and, in addition, employees are free to choose whether to join, stay, or leave a firm (Luo, Li, & Chan, 2020).
Thirdly, due to the permanent and long-term nature of capital investment, managers are usually less able to make frequent adjustments. On the other hand, managers can regularly increase or decrease investment in labor by hiring or firing (Hamermesh, 1995; Dixit & Pindyck, 2012). Therefore, in terms of resources, investment in labor gives managers more flexibility than investment in capital expenditures. Aksin, Cakan, Karaesmen, and Omeci (2015) assert that flexible resources can be adjusted to better meet uncertain demand.
Fourthly, unlike capital expenditures, over-investment (over-hiring and/or under-firing) or under-investment in labor (under-hiring and/or over-firing) has a direct impact on employees’ morale and productivity, thereby affecting the firm’s growth (Azadegan, Patel, & Parida, 2013; Mishina, Pollock, & Porack, 2004) and the firm’s long-term survival (Tatikonda, Terjesen, Patel, & Parida, 2013).
Prior studies suggest that over-investment in labor is more likely than under-investment to have a more negative impact on the firms’ profitability (Sualihu et al., 2021; Lee & Mo, 2020; Chen, Kacperczyk, & Ortiz-Molina, 2011). Since a politically-connected board could have access to political networks (González-Bailon et al., 2013), this could help firms to alleviate the negative impact of government policy and market uncertainty (Liu et al., 2021). Hence, our first and second research questions are:
Do politically-connected boards (PCBs) affect firms’ over-investment in labor? and
Do politically-connected boards (PCBs) affect firms’ under-investment in labor?
Furthermore, we investigate the impacts of the supervisory board (SB)’s optimal tenure on the association between PCBs and over-investment in labor. The SB in a two-tier board system in the Indonesian setting is referred to as the board of commissioners (BOC). The SB has a special power to suspend the members of a board of director (BOD) (Yap, Tan, & Lai, 2020) [3]. This is more likely to strengthen the role of the SB in supervising, monitoring and advising the BOD, which is in charge of the management of the firm’s business. Hence, it is also worth investigating the impacts of an SB on the association between PCBs and over-investment in labor. In this case, an SB in a two-tier board system that has optimal tenure may be better at fulfilling these responsibilities. However, in the literature, there are mixed findings for the effects of board tenure in a one-tier board system on various attributes including firm performance (Kor & Sundaramurthy, 2009; Huang & Hilary, 2018). Therefore, our third research question is:
Does the supervisory board (SB)’s optimal tenure influence the association between PCBs and firms’ over-investment in labor?
To address our research questions, we developed three hypotheses. To test these hypotheses, we used a sample of firms listed on the Indonesia Stock Exchange (IDX) from 2010 to 2019. We find that the presence of PCBs is negatively associated with over-investment in labor. On the other hand, the presence of PCBs has no effect on under-investment in labor. We also find that the negative association between PCBs and over-investment in labor is more pronounced for firms with optimal SB tenure. In our additional analysis, we find that the presence of PCBs is negatively associated with over-investment in labor through a higher dividend payout ratio.
Our study provides several important contributions. First, prior studies examine the impacts of various firm characteristics on labor investment (e.g. Jung et al., 2014; Khedmati et al., 2020; Cao & Rees, 2020; Habib & Hasan, 2021) and the effects of political connections on the capital investment (e.g. Chen, Sun, et al., 2011; Duchin & Sosyura, 2012; Cherkasova & Ivanova, 2019). Our study complements those studies on labor investment and political connections by specifically investigating the effects of politically-connected boards (PCBs) on over-(under-)investment in labor. Second, our study contributes to the literature on the importance of separating labor investment inefficiency into over- and under-investment because each has different implications for firms’ operations, in particular for those firms that have politically-connected boards (PCBs). Third, prior studies on board optimal tenure are focused on a one-tier board system. On the other hand, our study contributes to the literature on the role of the supervisory board’s optimal tenure in a two-tier board system in influencing the association between PCBs and over-investment in labor.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we present the theoretical background and hypothesis development. Section 3 discusses the sample selection, data sources and research method. Section 4 presents the results of our hypotheses testing, endogeneity testing and additional analyses. Section 5 concludes the findings, acknowledges the limitations of the study, and offers suggestions for future research.
2. Theoretical background and hypothesis development
2.1 Indonesian setting and political connections
Politically-connected firms are a global trend. Indonesia provides a distinctive setting for the study of political connections, particularly after the reforms introduced in 1998. The Indonesian political system has been transformed from a centralized, autocratic government to a more democratic system since President Soeharto stepped down from his position in 1998. For instance, instead of having only one powerful president (e.g. Soeharto for 32 years from 1966 to 1998), Indonesia has elected five different presidents over the last 24 years since 1998. Interestingly, since 2004, the last two presidents have been directly elected by the Indonesian people in the general elections (Harianto, 2020).
In addition to the major shift in the Indonesian political system and law reforms intended to establish a more democratic government, the focus of government has also shifted from reliance on natural resources to a more efficient economy in the service and manufacturing industry sectors which contribute to the employment of 45% (compared to only a third in 1990) and 21% (having become more prominent in recent years) of local workers, respectively [4]. The change in the Indonesian political and economic environment provides opportunities for researchers to further explore the role that political connections in Indonesia play in ensuring firms’ efficiency and success post-1998-reforms, particularly after the global financial crisis (GFC) in 2008.
Extant studies have found that political connections can affect firm value (Fisman, 2001; Goldman, Rocholl, & Jongil, 2009; Kim, Pantzalis, & Park, 2012; Fan & Chen, 2022). Gao, Martin, Hu, and Lu (2023) found that firms select new directors with political backgrounds as a strategic decision to build political capital to improve firm performance. Peng, Zhang, and Zhu (2017) found that political connections help firms to obtain long-term loans. Firms generally use a politician as a rent seeker (Krueger, 1974). El Nayal, Van Oosterhout, and Van Essen (2021) state that “politician-directors can supply firms with valuable, private knowledge of the inner workings of government. This can involve sharing information on loopholes in the bureaucracy, as well as the provision of a real-time insider’s view into the policymaking process” (p. 459–460). In this context, shareholders could appoint reputable former public officials and politicians to the board as a signal of their commitment to the firms and to the public (Bona-Sánchez, Pérez-Alemán, & Santana-Martín, 2014; Djankov, La Porta, Lopez-De-Silanes, & Shleifer, 2010). This will benefit not only politically-connected firms, but also those former politicians (Niessen & Ruenzi, 2010) and the economic development of the country (Claessens, 2006).
2.2 Politically-connected boards and over-investment in labor
Jensen and Meckling (1976) defined an agency relationship “as a contract under which one or more persons (the principal) engage another person (the agent) to perform some service on their behalf which involves delegating some decision-making authority to the agent” (p. 308). Agency theory assumes that individuals have self-interest, and therefore, their actions are more likely to be driven by their desire to maximize their own utility or wealth (Jensen & Meckling, 1976). Indonesia has a number of publicly-listed firms with high shareholding concentrations (Joni, Ahmed, & Hamilton, 2020). This has led to conflicts of interest between large shareholders (controlling shareholders) and minority shareholders (non-controlling shareholders) (Chang, 2003; Setia-Atmaja, Haman, & Tanewski, 2011). This type of conflict is referred to as “agency problem II” (principal-principal conflict) (Young, Peng, Ahlstrom, Bruton, & Jiang, 2008; Setia-Atmaja et al., 2011).
From the perspective of principal-principal relationship, the controlling shareholders and non-controlling shareholders have different interests regarding the potentially conflicting objectives of profit and growth (David, O'Brien, Yoshikawa, & Delios, 2010). This may also include the conflicts of interest involved in determining the level of investment in labor. Large shareholders (controlling shareholders) could enjoy the private benefits of control at the expense of minority shareholders (non-controlling shareholders) (Setia-Atmaja et al., 2011). The opponents of firms with high shareholding concentration assert that managers of such firms may misappropriate the firms’ resources for the benefit of the controlling shareholders as well as for their own benefit at the expense of non-controlling shareholders (Holderness & Sheehanm, 1988; Shleifer & Vishny, 1997; La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, & Vishny, 2000; Claessens, Djankov, Fan, & Lang, 2002; Setia-Atmaja et al., 2011). The controlling shareholders may misuse corporate resources by, for instance, subsidizing their personal loans, excessive remuneration for the members of the boards and the use of corporate assets for personal purposes (Sauerwald, Heugens, Turturea, & Essen, 2019).
As a country experiencing strong economic development with a compound annual growth rate (CAGR) of 5.1% over a ten-year period from 2013 to 2023 (World Economics, 2024) [5], Indonesia provides ample opportunities for entrepreneurs and investors to establish, develop and expand their businesses. In capitalizing on the growth potential of a business, managers of firms with a high shareholding concentration may opportunistically engage in empire building by increasing the size of labor forces in order to gain more prestige, power and rewards (Sualihu et al., 2021; Stein, 2003). This may encourage managers of such firms to increase their investment in labor.
On the other hand, the proponents of firms with high shareholding concentration assert that since large shareholders have invested a substantial amount of wealth in the firms and if they dominate the voting rights of the firms and control the board, they could use their appointed board to provide effective monitoring of the firms’ operations in order to ensure that managers will work in the best interests of the firms (Ang, Cole, & Lin, 2000; Anderson & Reeb, 2003; Ben-Amar & André, 2006). Moreover, from the stewardship perspective, managers with high ethical standards are more likely to behave like stewards in order to strengthen the trustworthiness and reputation of their firm (Aleksey, 2009; Zhang, Wei, Yang, & Zhu, 2018; Eddleston & Kellermanns, 2007; Tosi, Brownlee, Silva, & Katz, 2003). In line with the stewardship perspective and the arguments from the proponents of high shareholding concentration, we expect that the presence of PCBs may help to mitigate the principal-principal conflict. A weaker principal-principal conflict may encourage managers to aim for optimal labor forces by reducing over-investment in labor.
Given the fact that publicly-listed firms in Indonesia are dominated by those with a high concentration of shareholdings (Joni et al., 2020), we elaborate on the detrimental effects of over-investment in labor and the rationale for the beneficial effects of politically-connected boards (PCBs) in Indonesia in reducing over-investment in labor. Prior studies suggest that over-investment in labor may detrimentally affect the profitability, cash flows, productivity and reputation of firms. Firstly, it may be costly to firms in terms of additional labor expenses and its ongoing expenditures, thereby reducing the firms’ profitability and free cash flows (Bertrand & Mullainathan, 2003; Ghaly, Dang, & Stathopoulos, 2020; Jung et al., 2014; Sualihu et al., 2021). Secondly, over-investment in labor means that firms have a labor force that is larger than is actually required, which is likely to cause job insecurity and financial anxiety among employees which, in turn, affects their morale and reduces the firms’ productivity (Choi, Heo, Cho, & Lee, 2020). Finally, it is hard for managers to reduce the firms’ labor force because the decision to fire employees is difficult, particularly when firms are required to compensate employees with a lump sum employment termination payment. Moreover, unfair dismissal claims and union backlash may have a negative impact on firms’ reputation (Chen, Tong, Wang, & Zhang, 2019; Chen, Kacperczyk, et al., 2011; Chu, Haw, Ho, & Zhang, 2020; Jung et al., 2014).
In terms of operations management and in the absence of managerial opportunism to engage in empire building through larger labor forces, managers are generally interested in obtaining optimal labor forces by reducing over-investment in labor. However, dynamic market environments are more likely to cause market and/or demand uncertainty, which may prevent managers from securing an optimal labor force (Azadegan et al., 2013; Mishina et al., 2004). To avoid the negative repercussions of over-investment in labor, political connections could help firms to mitigate it. Amah (2022) states that “organizations have a means of steering participants away from the dark side to the bright side of political behavior which is useful for productivity” (p. 341). Furthermore, González-Bailon et al. (2013) explore in detail the attributes and importance of the firms’ politically-connected board members. They state that “For companies, the value of recruitment of these individuals to their board might be derived from general attributes (for example due to their reputation, prestige, governance or networking) or traits that are domain specific (such as technical expertise, ties to domestic industry or business overseas) or some combination of these reasons” (p. 852). Hence, shareholders could strategically appoint to the board former public officials and/or politicians with established reputations (González-Bailon et al., 2013; Bona-Sánchez et al., 2014). Moreover, the appointment of politically-connected board members can also offer significant benefits to former public officers and politicians in terms of social status and financial rewards (González-Bailon et al., 2013; Niessen & Ruenzi, 2010; Butler, Fauver, & Mortal, 2009). González-Bailon et al. (2013) also state that “For individuals, appointments to corporate boards provide a means for securing financial remuneration through directors’ salaries and also for obtaining nonfinancial benefits such as prestige or networking opportunities (for example maintaining professional status or regular involvement in public life)” (p. 851). By holding a prestigious position on the board of a publicly-listed firm offering a sizeable remuneration, members of a politically-connected board have actually pledged their personal reputation as an intangible collateral asset (Gilson, 2007). Therefore, they are more likely to make a rational choice to work in the best interests of the firm and shareholders because if they fail to perform their duties and fulfill responsibilities, they are more likely to lose their reputation and various privileges.
Since corporate directorship provides members of politically-connected boards with a source of income, prestige and regular involvement in public life, this could incentivize them to perform well on the board. Batta, Ricardo, and March (2014) found that due to their connections with high-level government and politicians, politically-connected firms have less risk of expropriation from the insiders and/or controlling shareholders. A politically-connected board is expected to provide better evaluative and informative advice to managers. This could help to curb managerial opportunism and engagement in empire building by means of establishing unnecessarily large labor forces.
Furthermore, as discussed earlier, Azadegan et al. (2013) and Mishina et al. (2004) suggest that the presence of market uncertainty prevents managers from establishing optimal labor forces. Politically-connected boards could also play an important role in mitigating this uncertainty. For example, a politically-connected board could assist public officials to understand the business and economic issues, thus enabling the government to adjust or formulate policies that benefit firms as well as the economy (Liedong, 2021). Faccio (2006) and Fisman (2001) also found that political connections can enhance firm value by helping firms to obtain valuable resources and deal with various external uncertainties. In addition, PCBs could also help firms to access new markets, increase sales, or obtain more rewarding government contracts, thereby reducing the uncertainties of market expansion (Agrawal & Knoeber, 2001; Dieleman & Sachs, 2008; Li, He, Lan, & Yiu, 2012; Li, Xia, & Zajac, 2018; Wu, Li, & Li, 2013).
Together with the previous arguments, and because PCBs have access to public officials and government resources, managers are able to predict market demands more accurately. In addition, better-quality PCBs could provide better evaluative and informative advice to managers. This enables managers to forecast their required labor force more precisely from time to time. A more accurate labor force forecast could prevent excessive labor forces. Therefore, it helps to reduce over-investment in labor and prevents managerial opportunism to engage in empire building through larger labor forces. Hence, we predict that PCBs could reduce firms’ over-investment in labor. To address the first research question (RQ1), we develop testable hypothesis 1.
The presence of politically-connected boards is negatively associated with the firms’ over-investment in labor.
2.3 Politically-connected boards and under-investment in labor
Publicly-listed firms in Indonesia are characterized by the presence of high shareholding concentrations. From the perspective of agency theory II (principal-principal conflict), the proponents of high shareholding concentration suggest that managers can maximize their own interests as well as those of both the controlling shareholders and the non-controlling shareholders (Ang et al., 2000; Anderson & Reeb, 2003; Ben-Amar & André, 2006). In these cases, managers may under-invest in labor in order to save labor costs, thus enabling them to record a higher profit outlook to indicate better financial performance aligned with their performance target. A better profit outlook is more likely to satisfy the interests of the managers and all shareholders.
Chen, Kacperczyk, et al., (2011) found that firms with under-investment in labor have better future performance due to savings from short-term labor hire. Managers of firms facing a labor shortage due to under-investment in labor could still deliver on a potentially profitable project by hiring temporary employees (Jung et al., 2014; Ghaly et al., 2020; Sualihu et al., 2021). Although this may not be an ideal solution in the long term, it does help firms to execute a profitable project that would increase firm value, which aligns the interests of managers with those of all shareholders. Furthermore, De Stefano, Bonet, and Camuffo (2019) assert that temporary employees provide flexibility since managers can hire or terminate them without legal consequences. In that regard, under-investment in labor is perceived to be less problematic and more manageable than over-investment in labor.
Based on the findings in the literature, under-investment in labor offers certain benefits (Chen, Kacperczyk, et al., 2011; De Stefano et al., 2019), managers are more likely to under-invest in labor because by doing so, firms incur less cost and risk. Under-investment in labor gives managers the flexibility to hire more employees when new business opportunities arise (Sualihu et al., 2021). If managers under-invest in labor, they can afford to increase their labor force when required. In addition, under-investment in labor is more manageable than over-investment because it is easier for managers to hire than to fire employees. The firing of employees could affect the management-employee relationship, demoralize employees, and reduce their productivity , which in turn, has a negative impact on firm growth (Sualihu et al., 2021; Lee & Mo, 2020; Chen, Kacperczyk, et al., 2011).
Since the managers may under-invest in labor in order to incur less cost and risk, this enables firms to record a better profit outlook. Hence, this strategy is expected to align the interests of managers with those of all shareholders, both controlling and non-controlling entities. Given the foregoing arguments, under-investment in labor is more manageable than over-investment in labor; hence, it is anticipated that the role of PCBs is weaker in firms with under-investment in labor. Therefore, we posit that there is no significant association between PCBs and under-investment in labor. To address the second research question (RQ2), testable hypothesis 2 is formulated:
There is no statistically significant association between politically-connected boards and firms’ under-investment in labor.
2.4 Role of supervisory board’ optimal tenure
Prior studies (Belot, Ginglinger, Slovin, & Sushka, 2014; Jungmann, 2006) assert that the two-tier board system is more suitable for dealing with the agency problems in a firm that has high shareholding, thus addressing the conflicts between major shareholders and minority shareholders. Publicly-listed firms in Indonesia have a high level of shareholding concentration. The two-tier board system in Indonesia is designed to protect the interests of both the shareholders and the public by separating the responsibilities of the supervisory board (SB) from those of the board of directors (BOD) (IFC and IFSA, 2014, 2018). In this two-tier board system, shareholders appoint an SB to represent them in a firm because they cannot directly interfere with the firm’s internal management.
As a steward of the firm, the SB supervises, monitors and advises the BOD, which is responsible for the firm’s management and operations (Khalil, Harianto, & Guney, 2022). In addition, the SB has a statutory right giving it special power over the BOD. When deemed necessary in order to protect the firm’s interests, the SB has the authority to temporarily suspend the members of the BOD (Yap et al., 2020). In order to do so, the SB members need to have adequate business experience and knowledge.
In Indonesia, the members of an SB are generally appointed by shareholders during the Annual General Meeting (AGM); their appointment is for five years and they can be re-elected for another five years, and so on. Prior studies suggest that board tenure has a significant impact on a firm’s strategic direction, monitoring mechanism, communication, financial performance and the quality of the financial report (Alves & Lourenço, 2023; Chu, Gupta, & Livne, 2021; Golden & Zajac, 2001; Li & Wahid, 2018; McGuinness, Lam, & Vieito, 2015; Sun & Bhuiyan, 2020).
Empirical studies provide mixed findings in terms of the association between the length of board tenure in a one-tier board and board effectiveness. Sun and Bhuiyan (2020) found that longer board tenure is associated with strategic changes and better financial reporting. Li and Wahid (2018) suggest that longer board tenure can provide better monitoring of management. Golden and Zajac (2001) assert that boards with longer tenure have more knowledge and understanding of business, which helps to improve communication between board members. However, Huang and Hillary (2018) argue that shorter (longer) board tenure may make a difference in the effectiveness of a firm’s governance. On the one hand, a shorter (longer) tenure may signal that the board is less (more) experienced and knowledgeable. A board with longer tenure is more likely to have better knowledge of the firm and therefore can provide better monitoring of management (e.g. Bacon & Brown, 1975; Beasley, 1996; Li & Wahid, 2018). On the other hand, shorter (longer) board tenure may indicate lower (higher) entrenchment [6], resulting in stronger (weaker) monitoring of management (Anderson, Mansi, & Reeb, 2004; Huang & Hilary, 2018; Li & Wahid, 2018). Jia (2017) found that boards with longer tenure influence the contributions of innovation outputs to the firms’ future value and performance.
Explaining these differences, Kor and Sundaramurthy (2009) and Huang and Hilary (2018) found that board tenure has an inverse U-shaped relationship with firm value, accounting performance, and quality of corporate decisions such as mergers and acquisitions, and financial reporting. Since there are mixed findings with regard to the association between board tenure and board effectiveness in a one-tier board system in the literature, we conjecture that the supervisory board’s optimal tenure in a two-tier board system may not affect the association between PCBs and over-investment in labor. To address the third research question (RQ3), we formulate non-directional hypothesis 3:
The supervisory board’s optimal tenure may not influence the association between politically-connected boards and the firms’ over-investment in labor.
3. Research method
3.1 Sample selection and data sources
Our sample consisted of firms listed on the Indonesia Stock Exchange (IDX) from 2010 to 2019. We excluded financial and utility firms from our sample since these two industry sectors have distinctive reporting systems and are also more heavily regulated than other industry sectors (Pittman & Fortin, 2004). We downloaded the financial variables from the Bloomberg database. Our main variables (e.g. political connections, supervisory board’ tenure and regional employment data) were manually collected from the firms’ annual reports. Our final sample comprised 260 firms listed on the IDX with 2,456 firm-year observations spanning a 10-year period from 2010 to 2019. Because data for some variables was missing, the number of observations was reduced accordingly for the testing of hypotheses 1, 2 and 3.
Panel A of Table 1 presents the details of the sample selection process. Panel B of Table 1 shows the industry distribution and representativeness of sample firms based on the Indonesia Stock Exchange (IDX) Industry Classification [7]. Firms in the property, consumer goods manufacturing, other services and mining industry sectors comprise 17.69, 11.15, 9.62 and 9.62% of the sample, respectively. The remaining industry sectors accounted for between 4.23 and 9.23% of the sample.
3.2 Multivariate analysis
We conducted the multivariate ordinary least squares (OLS) regression models depicted in Equations (1, 2 and 3) to test hypotheses 1, 2 and 3, respectively.
3.2.1 Dependent variable
The dependent variable in Equations (1 and 3) to test hypotheses 1 and 3 is over-investment in labor (OVER_LAB). On the other hand, in Equation (2), under-investment in labor (UNDER_LAB) is the dependent variable used to test hypothesis 2.
We measured over-(under-)investment in labor (OVER_LAB or UNDER_LAB) using a variation of Equation (4) employed by Mishina et al. (2004) [8].
Investors and analysts often assess a firm’s performance by comparing it with the industry norms. Using Equation (4), we measured over-investment in labor (OVER_LAB) and under-investment in labor (UNDER_LAB) by comparing labor investment of firm i in year t with the ratio of the total number of employees of all firms in the same industry sector in year t to the total annual sales for all firms in the same industry sector in year t (Mishina et al., 2004). Hence, OVER_LAB (UNDER_LAB) in firm i occurs when the ratio of the number of employees at the end of financial year t to the annual sales of firm i during year t is greater (lower) than the ratio of the total number of employees of all firms in the same industry sector in year t to the total annual sales for all firms in the same industry sector in year t.
Over-investment in labor is represented by the positive sign in Equation (4), and indicates that a firm has over-invested in labor compared to the industry norm. In the sub-sample of over-investment in labor, a higher (lower) positive number indicates a higher (lower) over-investment in labor. On the other hand, the negative sign in Equation (4) indicates that a firm has under-invested in labor relative to the industry norm. For ease of interpretation, the negative signs of the sub-sample for under-investment in labor are multiplied by −1 to obtain a positive number. Hence, a higher (lower) positive number indicates a higher (lower) under-investment in labor.
3.2.2 Explanatory variable
The presence of PCBs is the explanatory variable in Equations (1 and 2) used to test hypotheses 1 and 2. We applied a variation of the model employed by Faccio (2006), Chaney, Faccio, and Parsley (2011) and Arifin, Hasan, and Kabir (2020) to determine whether or not a firm has PCBs. Firms are considered as having PCBs if a member of the supervisory board and/or the board of directors is a former member of parliament or a former minister or a former high-ranking government official or a former public official, or has a close relationship with top politicians or a political party. Hence, the presence of PCBsit is a dummy variable set to 1 if firm i in year t has politically-connected board member(s) and zero (0) otherwise.
In Equation (3), the explanatory variable used to test hypothesis 3 is
3.2.3 Control variables
As suggested by extant studies, we included in Equations (1, 2 and 3) a number of control variables, that may affect the dependent variable. There are nine control variables including industry and year effects, namely TOP5it, LEVit, ROAit, DPRit, TANGit, OPER_CCit, Qit, INDUSTRYi and YEARt DUMMIES. Details of each variable are given in Appendix. To support our hypotheses 1 and 3, we expected the coefficients of explanatory variables to be significantly negative. For hypothesis 2, we expected the coefficient of the explanatory variable to be statistically insignificant. All variables including dependent variables, explanatory variables and control variables are summarized and defined in Appendix.
4. Results
4.1 Descriptive statistics and univariate analysis
Panel A of Table 2 shows the mean, median, 25th percentile and 75th percentile values of the key variables used in the empirical analysis. All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1 and 99% levels to mitigate the effect of outliers (Kennedy, 2003; Kraft, Leone, & Wasley, 2007). The mean (median) value of labor investment inefficiency (LAB_INEFFit), the proxy for labor investment inefficiency, is 9.6% (3.9%). Firms with PCBs accounted for 50.1% of the sample. The mean (median) value of return on assets (ROAit) is 4.4% (3.2%) compared to dividend payout ratio (DPRit) with a mean (median) value of 20.4% (0.0%). The sample firms are dominated by the top five largest shareholders (TOP 5it) with a mean (median) value of ownership percentage of 70.8% (73.2%). This suggests that publicly-listed firms in Indonesia have a high level of shareholding concentration. The leverage (LEVit) has a mean (median) value of 47.5% (47.8%), which is also supported by the asset tangibility ratio (TANGit) with a mean (median) value of 61.0% (56.4%). Tobin’s q (Qit) ratio, the proxy of firm growth, has a mean (median) value of 1.56 (1.05) and the operating cycle (OPER_CCit) has a mean (median) value of 5.02 (4.85). Panel B of Table 2 presents the results of the univariate tests in terms of both mean and median values of the key variables. It shows that the mean and median values of the key variables for the sub-sample of over-investment in labor (OVER_LABit) differ significantly from the sub-sample of under-investment in labor (UNDER_LABit).
4.2 Spearman correlation matrix
Table 3 shows the Spearman Correlation Matrix of all variables in the main regressions. The coefficients of correlation between variables are below 0.500 except between over-investment in labor (OVER_LABit) and under-investment in labor (UNDER_LABit), and between return on assets (ROAit) and dividend payout ratio (DPRit). We conducted the variance inflation factor (VIF) diagnostic test to ensure that there was no multicollinearity problem between variables (Thompson, Kim, Aloe, & Becker, 2017; Kennedy, 2003). The overall mean (maximum) VIF value is 1.22 (1.61), indicating that the variables have no multicollinearity issue.
4.3 Main results
4.3.1 Results of testing hypotheses 1 and 2
The results of testing hypothesis 1 are given in columns 1 and 2 of Table 4. The results show that the coefficient of PCBsit and the t-statistic value are −0.048 and −2,29, respectively. The coefficient of PCBsit is significantly negative at the 5% level. The results suggest that the presence of PCBs reduces firms’ over-investment in labor, thereby supporting hypothesis 1. The result is also economically significant as PCBs can reduce the level of over-investment in labor by 12.6%.
The coefficients of the control variables are as follows: the coefficient of TOP5it is not statistically significantly associated with over-investment in labor. The coefficients of LEVit, ROAit and DPRit are negative and statistically significant at the 5, 1 and 5% levels, respectively. The results indicate that a higher leverage (LEVit) encourages firms to act more carefully in their human resources recruitment strategy so as not to impose an unnecessary financial burden on themselves (Bae, Kang, & Wang, 2011), and that more efficient investment in labor is associated with better firm performance (ROAit) (Ferguson & Reio, 2010; Michie & Sheehan, 2005) and higher devidend payment ratio (DPR) (Michiels, Uhlaner, & Dekker, 2017). Meanwhile, the coefficients of TANGit, OPER_CCit and Qit are positive and statistically significant at the 1, 5 and 10% levels, respectively. These results are consistent with the assumption that a greater number of fixed assets acquired by a firm (TANGit), especially when empire building, will also increase investments in other internal resources, including the labor force (Franzoni, 2009). In addition, when opportunities for further growth arise (Qit), firms may be spurred to hire more employees than required (Mishina et al., 2004). Furthermore, firms with poor (good) management of inventory and accounts receivable (OPER_CCit) have higher (lower) over-investment in labor (Becker & Huselid, 2006).
In columns 2 and 3 of Table 4, we report the coefficient and t-statistic value of PCBsit, which are −0.001 and −0.29, respectively. The results suggest that the coefficient of PCBsit is not statistically significant. In other words, the presence of PCBsit is not statistically and significantly associated with firms’ under-investment in labor. Hence, hypothesis 2 is supported.
4.3.2 Results of testing hypothesis 3
We report the results of testing hypothesis 3 in columns 1 and 2 of Table 5. Hypothesis 3 predicts that SB’s optimal tenure does not influence the negative association between PCBs and the firms’ over-investment in labor. Columns 1 and 2 of Table 5 show that the coefficient and t-statistic value of interaction between PCBsit and the optimal tenure of an SB (SB_TENRit) if we use the SB’s optimal tenure of five to ten years. The coefficient of PCBsit*SB_TENRit is −0.085 and −3.53, respectively. Hence, the results do not support hypothesis 3. The findings show that the coefficient of PCBsit*SB_TENRit is significantly negative at the 1% level, suggesting that the SB’s optimal tenure strengthens the negative association between PCBs and over-investment in labor. As an additional analysis, we followed Huang and Hilary (2018), who used an optimal tenure of eight to eleven years. Columns 3 and 4 of Table 5 show that the coefficient and t-statistic value of the interaction between PCBsit and the optimal tenure of SBs (SB_TENRit) if we use SB’s optimal tenure of eight to eleven years. The coefficient of PCBsit*SB_TENRit is −0.059 and −2.40, respectively. The results show that the coefficient of PCBsit*SB_TENRit is statistically and significantly negative at the 5% level. The findings confirm the results given in columns 1 and 2 of Table 5, thereby supporting the main results that the SB’s optimal tenure strengthens the negative association between PCBs and over-investment in labor. The results demonstrate that an SB with a tenure of five to ten years or eight to eleven years strengthens the negative association between PCBs and over-investment in labor. Usually, the members of an SB in publicly-listed firms in Indonesia are appointed for five years, with our findings suggesting that firms benefit from the re-appointment of SB members for a second term or more.
4.4 Endogeneity testing
4.4.1 Two-stage least squares (2SLS) regression model
Firms can choose whether or not to appoint former public officials and politicians to the boards, which has the potential to create an endogeneity problem. To address this potential endogeneity issue of having PCBsit and the reverse causality between the labor investment inefficiency (over-investment in labor/OVER_LABit and under-investment in labor/UNDER_LABit) and PCBsit in our main regression, we applied the Heckman treatment effect using a two-stage least square (2SLS) regression model, commonly used as a robustness test by prior studies on political connections (Kim & Zhang, 2016; Wu, Wu, & Rui, 2012).
The 2SLS regression model requires valid and relevant instrumental variable(s) in the first-stage regression that is later excluded from the second-stage regression. We applied two instruments that have been suggested by prior studies on political connections: the average age of public officials (An, Chen, Luo, & Zhang, 2016; Xu, Chen, Xu, & Chan, 2016) and the average education level of public officials (An et al., 2016), in the first-stage regression. An et al. (2016) argue that these two instrumental variables are valid and relevant because the experience and knowledge of public officials, which relate to their age and education level, can affect the probability of the public official changes, but they are not directly related to a corporate investment. Using the same logic, Xu et al. (2016) also found that the age affects the probability of the individuals’ potential new appointment to a position as a public official, but it can not directly influence the firm’s cash holdings.
Applying the logic from both An et al. (2016) and Xu et al. (2016), we assumed that the age and education level of former public officials can affect their appointment to the PCBs, but they are not directly related to the firm’s labor investment. Hence, we used two instrumental variables (1) average age of board members of firm i in year t (AVG_BOARD_AGEit) (An et al., 2016; Xu et al., 2016) and; (2) average education level of board members of firm i in year t (AVG_BOARD_EDUit) (An et al., 2016) in the first-stage regression. However, to ensure that these two instruments are robust and reliable, we ran the Cragg-Donald F-test to check the strength and relevance of these two instruments. Consistent with An et al. (2016), we also performed the Kleibergen-Paap rk Wald F-statistic test. In addition, we conducted the Sargan-Hansen J-test to check the exogeneity or validity of these two instruments.
The results of the tests show that the Cragg-Donald F-statistic score and the Kleibergen-Paap rk Wald F-statistic score are 171.77 (p-value 0.000) and 30.68, respectively. Both of these scores are higher than the Stock-Yogo (2005) weak ID test critical values at 10% (19.93), indicating that those two instrumental variables used in the first-stage regression are strong therefore they are robust and relevant. Further, the score of the Sargan-Hansen J-test is 0.162 (p-value 0.6869), which is statistically insignificant. The result of the Sargan-Hansen J-test confirms the exogeneity of these two instrumental variables, suggesting that they are valid and appropriate for the first-first- and second-stage regressions. Overall, the results of the Cragg-Donald F-test and the Kleibergen-Paap rk Wald F-statistic test, as well as the Sargan-Hansen J-test supported our assumption that these two instrumental variables-(AVG_BOARD_AGEit) and (AVG_BOARD_EDUit) are valid and relevant for the 2SLS regression model.
After performing the first-stage regression (see Equation (5)), we obtained the inverse mills ratio (IMRit) by using the estimated results for PCBsit from the first-stage regression, and incorporated the IMR in the second-stage least square regression (see Equation (6)). For the second-stage regression, we applied the following models:
Panels A and B of Table 6 show the results from the first-stage and second-stage Heckman 2SLS regression models. The coefficients of both instruments are significant at the 1% level, further indicating that they are strong and valid instruments for PCBsit. The IMR coefficients in the second-stage regression are also significant, indicating the existence of an endogeneity problem. Columns 3 (4) of Table 6 report that the coefficient of PCBsit is −0.189 (t-statistic value = −3.87). The results suggest that the presence of PCBs is negatively associated with over-investment in labor at the 1% level, which supports our hypothesis 1. On the other hand, columns 5 (6) of Table 6 show that the coefficient of PCBsit is −0.007 (t-statistic value = −1.32). The results confirm our hypothesis 2: that the presence of PCBsit is not significantly associated with under-investment in labor. Overall, the results for PCBsit are qualitatively similar to the main results as reported in Table 4 [9].
4.4.2 Entropy balancing
In addition to the endogeneity testing using the Heckman treatment effect-two-stage least square (2SLS) regression model, we employed entropy balancing to validate our main results. Entropy balancing is a data pre-processing procedure for a binary variable prior to the subsequent determination of the treatment effect. Entropy balancing can be seen as a generalization of the propensity score weighting approach (Hainmueller, 2012; Hainmueller & Xu, 2013).
The results of our entropy balancing test are presented in columns 1 to 4 of Table 7. Columns 1 and 2 report that the coefficient of PCBsit and t-statistic value are −0.046 and −5.14, respectively. The results show that PCBsit is significantly associated with over-investment in labor (OVER_LABit) at the 1% level. Further, columns 3 and 4 show that the coefficient of PCBsit and t-statistic value are 0.002 and 1.47, respectively. The results show that the presence of PCBsit is not significantly associated with under-investment in labor (UNDER_LABit). All these results are qualitatively similar to the main findings reported in Table 4 [10].
4.5 Additional analyses
4.5.1 Additional control variables
Because in this study, we investigated the effects of PCBs on over-(under-)investment in labor, and to ensure that our results remained robust with the inclusion of board related characteristics as suggested by prior studies: the average board age (AVG_BOARD_AGEit) (An et al., 2016; Xu et al., 2016), the average board education level (AVG_BOARD_EDUit) (An et al., 2016), the proportion of independent members on the supervisory board (INDEP_SBit) (El Ammari, 2023) and the proportion of female members on the board (FEM_BOARDit) (Proença, Augusto, & Murteira, 2020).
Columns 1 and 2 of Table 8 show that the coefficient of PCBsit and t-statistic value are −0.050 and −2.17 at the 5% level, respectively. In contrast, columns 3 and 4 of Table 8 show that the coefficient of PCBsit and t-statistic value are −0.001 and −0.01 at the insignificant level, respectively. The findings are qualitatively similar to the main results reported in Table 4: that PCBsit reduces over-investment in labor but it has no influence on under-investment in labor.
4.5.2 Alternative proxies for over-(under-)investment in labor
Scharfstein and Stein (1990) assert that managers often make investment decisions using similar firms in the same industry as a reference. To check the robustness of the main results presented in Table 4, we employed alternative proxies for over-(under-)investment in labor. These proxies use the industry-adjusted ratio as a benchmark (Azadegan et al., 2013). Hence, to capture over-(under-) investment in labor using the mentioned approach, we employed Equations (7a and 7b) as follows.
Equation 7a is defined as follows: Over-(under-)investment in labor in firm i occurs when the ratio of the number of employees at the end of financial year t to the annual sales of firm i during year t is greater (lower) than the mean value of this ratio for all firms in the same industry sector in year t.
Equation 7b is defined as follows: Over-(under-)investment in labor in firm i occurs when the ratio of the number of employees at the end of financial year t to the annual sales of firm i during year t is greater (lower) than the median value of this ratio for all firms in the same industry sector in year t.
In the sub-sample of over-investment in labor, a higher (lower) positive number indicates a higher (lower) over-investment in labor. For ease of interpretation, the negative signs of the sub-sample for under-investment in labor are multiplied by −1 to obtain a positive number. Hence, a higher (lower) positive number indicates a higher (lower) under-investment in labor.
Using the industry mean (Equation 7a) as a benchmark, the coefficient and t-statistic value of PCBsit in columns 1 and 2 of Table 9 are −0.051 and −2.46, at the 5% level, respectively, for the over-investment regression. On the other hand, the coefficient and t-statistic value of PCBsit in columns 3 and 4 of Table 9 are −0.001 and −0.22 at the insignificant level, respectively, for the under-investment regression. The findings show that the presence of PCBsit reduces over-investment in labor but it has no influence on under-investment in labor.
Using the industry median (Equation 7b) as a benchmark, the coefficient and t-statistic value of PCBsit in columns 5 and 6 of Table 9 are −0.055 and −2.52 at the 5% level, respectively, for the over-investment regression. On the other hand, the coefficient and t-statistic value of PCBsit in columns 7 and 8 of Table 9 are 0.001 and 0.21 at the insignificant level, respectively, for the under-investment regression. The findings show that the presence of PCBs reduces over-investment in labor but it has no influence on under-investment in labor. Overall, employing Equations 7a (industry mean) and 7b (industry median), columns 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7 and 8 of Table 9 show that the results remain qualitatively the same as reported in Table 4.
4.5.3 Alternative proxies for politically-connected boards
In our main analysis, the presence of PCBsit is a dummy variable set to 1 if firm i in year t has politically-connected board member(s) and zero (0) otherwise. For the robustness check, we employ NUMPCBsit as the alternative proxy for PCBsit using a continuous variable which captures the number of politically-connected board members on the boards of firm i in year t. A continuous variable could provide more statistical power to detect differences among politically-connected firms and between politically connected firms and non-politically-connected firms.
Columns 1 and 2 of Table 10 show the coefficient and t-statistic value of NUMPCBsit, which are −0.048 and −2.29 at the 5% level, respectively. The results show that NUMPCBsit, which is the number of politically-connected members on the boards reduces over-investment in labor. On the other hand, columns 3 and 4 of Table 10 show the coefficient and t-statistic value of NUMPCBsit, which are −0.001 and −0.29, respectively. The results are not statistically significant, confirming that the number of politically-connected members on the boards (NUMPCBsit) has no influence on under-investment in labor. Overall, the results are qualitatively similar to the main findings presented in Table 4.
4.5.4 Channel analysis through the dividend payout ratio (DPR)
As discussed earlier, publicly-listed firms in Indonesia are characterized by the presence of high shareholding concentration, which causes agency problem II (principal-principal conflict). Some studies have found that the principal-principal relationship gives large shareholders the private benefits associated with control at the expense of minority shareholders (Holderness & Sheehanm, 1988; Shleifer & Vishny, 1997; La Porta et al., 2000; Claessens et al., 2002; Setia-Atmaja et al., 2011). On the other hand, prior studies have concluded that the presence of high shareholding concentration offers benefits to all shareholders (Ang et al., 2000; Anderson & Reeb, 2003; Ben-Amar & André, 2006; Zahra, Filatotchev, & Wright, 2009; Sauerwald et al., 2019). Moreover, Zahra et al. (2009) and Sauerwald et al. (2019) assert that in addition to the private benefits of control, through their appointed board, controlling shareholders have an incentive to improve the firm’s performance, which creates shared benefits for all shareholders. Better firm performance enables the board to pay higher dividends to shareholders (Su, Fung, Huang, & Shen, 2014).
By testing hypothesis 1, we found that the presence of PCBs reduces over-investment in labor, but we did not consider the channel (Liang, Fu, & Jiang, 2024) through which PCBs may affect over-investment in labor. To perform the channel analysis, we employed the two-step regression model suggested by Liang et al. (2024).
First step:
Second step:
All variables are defined in Equations (1 to 3) and also in Appendix.
In the regression models depicted in Equations (8a and 8b), CHANNEL is a mediation variable which can be replaced with a specific indicator. If the coefficient of PCBsit in the first-step regression model depicted in Equation (8a) is statistically significant, we perform the second-step regression model depicted in Equation (8b). If the coefficients of the second-step regression model for both the PCBsit and the mediation variable are statistically significant, the results suggest a partial mediation effect. If only the coefficient of the mediation variable is statistically significant, the result suggests a complete mediation effect (Liang et al., 2024).
Firms with better performance are more likely to pay higher dividends. Lin, Xin & Li (2021) found that firms with strong political connections have a higher dividend payout ratio. Su et al. (2014) assert that cash dividends are shared proportionately among the controlling shareholders and the minority shareholders; therefore, a higher dividend payout ratio is more likely to reduce the principal-principal conflict of firms with strong political connections. Therefore, in the presence of high-shareholding concentration, the presence of PCBsit is expected to increase the dividend payout ratio (DPRit). Chen, Kacperczyk, et al., (2011) found that firms without over-investment in labor have better performance. This encourages politically-connected boards to increase the firm’s operational efficiency by reducing over-investment in labor in order to increase firm performance.
In Equations (8a and 8b), CHANNEL is the dividend payout ratio (DPRit), which is used as the mediation variable. DPRit is computed as total dividend payments scaled by net income of firm i in year t. In the first step of the regression model (Equation (8a)), the dependent variable is the dividend payout ratio of firm i in year t (DPRit). The explanatory variable is politically-connected boards of firm i in year t (PCBsit). In columns 1 and 2 of Table 11, we report the coefficient and t-statistic value of PCBsit, which are 0.058 and 2.61 at the 5% level, respectively. The results suggest that the presence of PCBsit is positively associated with the dividend payout ratio (DPRit). In other words, the presence of PCBsit increases the firms’ dividend payout ratio (DPRit). In the second step of the regression model as depicted in Equation (8b), the explanatory variable is the presence of PCBsit. On the other hand, DPRit is the mediation variable. In columns 3 and 4 of Table 11, we report the coefficients of PCBsit and DPRit, which are −0.048 and −0.034 and t-statistic values of −2.29 and −2.24, respectively, both at the 5% level. Since both variables, namely PCBsit and DPRit are significantly negatively associated with over-investment in labor of firm i in year t (OVER_LABit), the results suggest that when DPRit is used as a channel, there are partly mediation effects. The findings suggest that the presence of PCBsit reduces over-investment in labor by increasing the dividend payout ratio (DPRit).
5. Conclusion
In a country with strong economic growth, firms are exposed to a wide range of market expansion opportunities, which may lead to over-investment in labor. To take advantage of such opportunities, firms often establish political connections by, for example, strategically appointing former public officers and politicians to their boards. Politically-connected boards (PCBs) could help firms to access new markets and obtain lucrative government contracts, thereby reducing the uncertainties of market expansion (Agrawal & Knoeber, 2001; Dieleman & Sachs, 2008; Li et al., 2012, 2018; Wu et al., 2013). This enables managers to forecast customer demands and their labor force requirements more accurately. In such cases, PCBs could prevent excessive investment in labor and mitigate managerial opportunism, which is a means of empire building through the acquisition of larger labor forces.
We find that the presence of PCBs reduces a firm’s over-investment in labor. Unlike over-investment in labor, which is risky and costly to firms, under-investment gives firms the flexibility to increase their labor force when required. Consistent with our prediction, we find that the presence of PCBs is not significantly associated with the firm’s under-investment in labor. In addition, we find that a supervisory board (SB) with optimal tenure strengthens the negative association between the PCBs and over-investment in labor. In other words, the role of the PCB in reducing over-investment in labor is more pronounced in those firms that have optimal tenure for their SB members. In our channel analysis, we find that the presence of PCBs reduces over-investment in labor through a higher dividend payout ratio.
Our study offers several practical implications and insights to stakeholders (e.g. insiders or management, shareholders, investors, analysts and creditors) in the following ways. First, our study highlights significant differences between capital investment and labor investment. For instance, labor investment is considered an expense rather than an asset (Wyatt, 2008) because, although such investment is human capital and is not recognized on the firm’s balance sheet (Boon et al., 2017). In addition, labor investment is characterized by: its flexibility which enables firms to make frequent adjustments (Hamermesh, 1995; Dixit & Pindyck, 2012; Aksin et al., 2015), its non-homogeneity since every employee is unique (Luo et al., 2020), its direct impact on morale and productivity of a firm (Azadegan et al., 2013; Mishina et al., 2004; Tatikonda et al., 2013), and its financial outlay which affects the ongoing cash flows of a firm (Sualihu et al., 2021; Khedmati et al., 2020; Merz & Yashiv, 2007). Second, our findings reveal that the presence of PCBs could help to reduce over-investment in labor. However, if managers of a firm choose to under-invest in labor in order to obtain better profit in the short-term through cost saving, they should be aware of the potential consequences of facing a financial loss when a new business opportunity suddenly arises which requires a larger labor force. Third, our findings help stakeholders to re-focus on the labor investment. This is crucial due to the fact that labor investment is often neglected by those stakeholders because the expenditure of labor investment is not recognized on the firm’s balance sheet as an asset. Instead, it is written off as an expense in the firm’s income statement. Fourth, our findings also provide insightful information to stakeholders, suggesting that an SB with optimal tenure is more committed to a firm, and this factor plays an important role in strengthening the negative association between PCBs and over-investment in labor. Fifth, our findings provide a valuable understanding of the effects of PCBs on over-(under-)investment in labor. Stakeholders could use information disclosed in the financial statements of a publicly-listed firm to determine the extent of the firm’s investment in labor and PCBs, and compare this information with similar firms in the same industry sector. Sixth, our findings give a better understanding of the association between investment in labor and political connections , which are human and social capital that could determine the long-term survival and success of a firm. Lastly, for shareholders, the appointment of board members with political connections is an important strategic decision to build political capital, which is likely to have a long-term impact on the financial performance of a firm; therefore, it requires thoughtful consultation with firm insiders.
Our study has several limitations. Due to the unavailability of data in firms’ annual reports regarding the number of poorly-skilled and highly skilled employees, we were not able to examine the effect of low-skilled and high-skilled employees on over-investment in labor. Also, we were not able to examine over-(under-)investment in labor by drawing a distinction between general (generalist) and firm-specific human capital (specialist) as suggested by Sevcenko, Wu, & Kacperczyk (2022). Generally, it is more difficult for managers to hire highly-skilled employees, specialists in particular, thereby driving the choice of either over- or under-investing in the labor forces. In addition, in the firms’ annual reports, there is no information regarding temporary employees. Therefore, if and when such data become available, this would provide another avenue for future research.
Descriptive statistics and univariate analysis
Panel A: Descriptive statistics – Whole sample | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Variable | Mean | Median | 25th | 75th | SD |
LAB_INEFFit* | 0.096 | 0.039 | 0.016 | 0.089 | 0.159 |
PCBsit | 0.501ˆ | 1.000 | 0.000 | 1.000 | 0.500 |
TOP5it | 0.708 | 0.732 | 0.592 | 0.858 | 0.181 |
LEVit | 0.475 | 0.478 | 0.311 | 0.632 | 0.209 |
ROAit | 0.044 | 0.032 | 0.003 | 0.076 | 0.087 |
DPRit | 0.204 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.306 | 0.349 |
TANGit | 0.610 | 0.564 | 0.299 | 0.876 | 0.414 |
OPER_CCit | 5.019 | 4.851 | 4.395 | 5.459 | 1.012 |
Qit | 1.562 | 1.051 | 0.824 | 1.665 | 1.600 |
Panel B: Univariate analysis – OVER_LAB & UNDER_LAB | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Mean | Median | |||||
Over | Under | t-test | Over | Under | M-W U test | |
LAB_INEFFit | 0.143 | 0.030 | 18.868*** | 0.063 | 0.025 | 19.819*** |
PCBsit | 0.460ˆ | 0.562ˆ | −4.997*** | 0.000 | 1.000 | −4.973*** |
TOP5it | 0.699 | 0.722 | −2.994*** | 0.730 | 0.736 | −2.768*** |
LEVit | 0.459 | 0.506 | −7.693*** | 0.464 | 0.506 | −7.447*** |
ROAit | 0.034 | 0.063 | −9.593*** | 0.027 | 0.047 | −9.031*** |
DPRit | 0.172 | 0.258 | −5.644*** | 0.000 | 0.130 | −8.330*** |
TANGit | 0.629 | 0.574 | 3.887*** | 0.593 | 0.513 | 5.222*** |
OPER_CCit | 5.121 | 4.847 | 7.332*** | 4.949 | 4.730 | 7.204*** |
Qit | 1.411 | 1.843 | −6.149*** | 1.004 | 1.168 | −7.517*** |
Note(s): *The labor investment inefficiency (LAB_INEFFit) includes both OVER_LABit and UNDER_LABit. ˆThe proportion of firms, rather than the mean proportion for the associated variable. The definitions of variables are presented in Appendix
Source(s): Table 2 by authors
Spearman correlation matrix
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | (9) | (10) | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(1) | OVER_LABit | ||||||||||
(2) | UNDER_LABit 0.845*** | ||||||||||
(3) | PCBsit | −0.155*** | −0.089*** | ||||||||
(4) | TOP5it | −0.039*** | −0.078*** | −0.107*** | |||||||
(5) | LEVit | −0.158*** | −0.163*** | 0.055*** | −0.024 | ||||||
(6) | ROAit | −0.217*** | −0.164*** | 0.07*** | 0.076*** | −0.296*** | |||||
(7) | DPRit | −0.228*** | −0.163*** | 0.12*** | 0.032 | −0.139*** | 0.553*** | ||||
(8) | TANGit | 0.145*** | 0.13*** | −0.078*** | 0.058*** | 0.033 | −0.138*** | −0.082*** | |||
(9) | OPER_CCit | 0.149*** | 0.137*** | −0.025 | −0.199*** | −0.094*** | −0.129*** | −0.131*** | −0.289*** | ||
(10) | Qit | −0.148*** | −0.139*** | 0.143*** | 0.071*** | 0.017 | 0.477*** | 0.343*** | −0.062*** | −0.139*** |
Note(s): All variables are summarized and defined in Appendix. The overall mean (maximum) VIF value is 1.22 (1.61) indicating that there is no multicollinearity issue between variables. *, **, and *** indicate the significance of coefficients at the 10, 5 and 1% levels, respectively
Source(s): Table 3 by authors
The effects of politically-connected boards (PCBs) on over-investment in labor (OVER_LAB) and under-investment in labor (UNDER_LAB)
OVER_LAB | UNDER_LAB | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
Coefficient | t-values | Coefficient | t-values | |
#1 | #2 | #3 | #4 | |
PCBsit | −0.048** | (−2.29) | −0.001 | (−0.29) |
TOP5it | −0.032 | (−0.66) | 0.008 | (1.15) |
LEVit | −0.117** | (−2.14) | 0.007 | (0.92) |
ROAit | −0.406*** | (−3.83) | −0.017 | (−1.01) |
DPRit | −0.034** | (−2.24) | −0.002 | (−0.79) |
TANGit | 0.086*** | (2.89) | −0.007** | (−1.98) |
OPER_CCit | 0.029** | (2.52) | −0.004** | (−2.15) |
Qit | 0.014* | (1.81) | 0.001 | (0.99) |
Constant | 0.247** | (2.48) | 0.100*** | (7.32) |
INDUSTRY FE | Yes | Yes | ||
YEAR FE | Yes | Yes | ||
Observations | 1,439 | 1,017 | ||
F | 5.14*** | 10.65*** | ||
R2 | 0.269 | 0.421 |
Note(s): Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regression model, t-statistics calculated based on the robust standard errors clustered at firm-level. Over-(under)investment in labor (OVER_LABit or UNDER_LABit) in firm i occurs when the ratio of the number of employees at the end of financial year t to the annual sales of firm i during year t is greater (lower) than the ratio of the total number of employees of all firms in the same industry sector in year t to the total annual sales for all firms in the same industry sector in year t. In the sub-sample of over-investment in labor, a higher (lower) positive number indicates a higher (lower) over-investment in labor. For ease of interpretation, the negative signs of the sub-sample for under-investment in labor are multiplied by −1 to obtain a positive number. Hence, a higher (lower) positive number indicates a higher (lower) under-investment in labor. The presence of PCBsit is a dummy variable set to 1 if firm i in year t has politically-connected board member(s) and zero (0) otherwise. Columns 1 and 2 report the OVER_LAB regression coefficients and t-values in parentheses, columns 3–4 report the UNDER_LAB regression coefficients and t-values in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1% levels, respectively (two-tailed). The definitions of variables are presented in Appendix
Source(s): Table 4 by authors
Effect of supervisory board’s optimal tenure (SB_TENR) on the relationship between politically-connected boards (PCBs) and over-investment in labor (OVER_LAB)
Optimal tenure = 5–10 years | Optimal tenure = 8–11 years | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
OVER_LAB | OVER_LAB | |||
Coefficient | t-values | Coefficient | t-values | |
#1 | #2 | #3 | #4 | |
PCBsit | −0.050* | (−1.75) | −0.054** | (−2.30) |
SB_TENRit | −0.041** | (−2.11) | −0.031* | (−1.65) |
PCBsitxSB_TENRit | −0.085*** | (−3.53) | −0.059** | (−2.40) |
TOP5it | −0.045 | (−0.89) | −0.037 | (−0.73) |
LEVit | −0.122** | (−2.25) | −0.120** | (−2.20) |
ROAit | −0.403*** | (−3.81) | −0.412*** | (−3.90) |
DPRit | −0.033** | (−2.19) | −0.032** | (−2.15) |
TANGit | 0.090*** | (3.02) | 0.088*** | (2.95) |
OPER_CCit | 0.027** | (2.43) | 0.028** | (2.48) |
Qit | 0.013 | (1.59) | 0.013* | (1.70) |
Constant | 0.284*** | (2.75) | 0.258** | (2.55) |
Industry FE | Yes | Yes | ||
Year FE | Yes | Yes | ||
Observations | 1,437 | 1,437 | ||
F | 5.22*** | 5.38*** | ||
R2 | 0.279 | 0.271 |
Note(s): Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regression model, t-statistics calculated based on the robust standard errors clustered at firm-level. Over-investment in labor (OVER_LABit) in firm i occurs when the ratio of the number of employees at the end of financial year t to the annual sales of firm i during year t is greater than the ratio of the total number of employees of all firms in the same industry sector in year t to the total annual sales for all firms in the same industry sector in year t. In the sub-sample of over-investment in labor, a higher (lower) positive number indicates a higher (lower) over-investment in labor. The presence of PCBs is a dummy variable set to 1 if a firm has politically-connected board member(s) and zero (0) otherwise. Columns 1, 2, 3 and 4 report the coefficients and t-statistic values of the interaction between PCBsit and SB_TENRit (SB’s optimal tenure). SB_TENRit is a dummy variable set to 1 if the average of SB tenure of firm i in year t is between 5–10 years (Columns 1 and 2) or 8–11 years (Columns 3 and 4) and zero (0) otherwise. t-values are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1% levels, respectively (two-tailed). The definitions of variables are presented in Appendix
Source(s): Table 5 by authors
Endogeneity testing using the Heckman treatment effect using a two-stage least square (2SLS) regression model: The relationship between politically-connected boards (PCBs) and over-(under-)investment in labor (OVER_LAB or UNDER_LAB)
Panel A. 1st stage regression | Panel B. 2nd stage regression | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Variable | PCBs | OVER_LAB | UNDER_LAB | |||
Coefficient | t-values | Coefficient | t-values | Coefficient | t-values | |
#1 | #2 | #3 | #4 | #5 | #6 | |
PCBsit | −0.189*** | (−3.87) | −0.007 | (−1.32) | ||
AVG_BOARD_AGEit | 0.057*** | (4.82) | −0.036 | (−0.72) | 0.008 | (1.05) |
AVG_BOARD_EDUit | 0.928*** | (5.32) | −0.080 | (−1.40) | 0.007 | (0.97) |
TOP5it | −0.515 | (−1.31) | −0.379*** | (−3.67) | −0.015 | (−0.89) |
LEVit | 0.514 | (1.39) | −0.016 | (−1.05) | −0.002 | (−0.60) |
ROAit | 0.571 | (0.81) | 0.073** | (2.52) | −0.006* | (−1.84) |
DPRit | 0.194 | (1.57) | 0.029** | (2.57) | −0.004** | (−2.20) |
TANGit | 0.064 | (0.33) | 0.016** | (2.08) | 0.001 | (1.17) |
OPER_CCit | 0.020 | (0.25) | 0.103*** | (3.14) | 0.004 | (1.28) |
Qit | 0.102** | (2.50) | 0.302*** | (2.95) | 0.103*** | (7.54) |
IMRit | −0.189*** | (−3.87) | −0.007 | (−1.32) | ||
Constant | −5.618*** | (−5.15) | −0.036 | (−0.72) | 0.008 | (1.05) |
Industry FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | |||
Year FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | |||
Observations | 2,442 | 1,429 | 1,013 | |||
Wald Joint | 87.47*** | |||||
Pseudo R2 | 0.176 | |||||
F | 5.49*** | 11.78*** | ||||
R2 | 0.293 | 0.424 |
Note(s): Heckman two-stage model, t-statistics calculated based on the robust standard errors clustered at firm-level. Columns 1 to 4 report the regression coefficients and t-statistic values in parentheses. Panel A reports the first-stage probit regression between PCBsit with instrumental variables (AVG_BOARD_AGEit and AVG_BOARD_EDUit) and the control variables used in the second-stage regression. Panel B reports the second-stage regression results. Labor investment inefficiency is measured as over-investment in labor (OVER_LABit) and under-investment in labor (UNDER_LABit). The presence of PCBsit is a dummy variable set to 1 if firm i in year t has politically-connected board member(s) and zero (0) otherwise. Columns 3–4 report the OVER_LAB regression coefficients and t-statistic values in parentheses, columns 5–6 report the UNDER_LAB regression coefficients and t-statistic values in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1% levels, respectively (two-tailed). The definitions of variables are presented in Appendix
Source(s): Table 6 by authors
Robustness test using entropy balancing - The effects of politically-connected boards (PCBs) on over-(under-)investment in labor (OVER_LAB or UNDER_LAB)
OVER_LAB | UNDER_LAB | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
Coefficient | t-values | Coefficient | t-values | |
#1 | #2 | #3 | #4 | |
PCBsit | −0.046*** | (−5.14) | 0.002 | (1.47) |
TOP5it | −0.015 | (−0.61) | 0.009** | (2.36) |
LEVit | −0.106*** | (−4.07) | 0.007* | (1.86) |
ROAit | −0.404*** | (−5.21) | −0.010 | (−0.97) |
DPRit | −0.028** | (−2.47) | −0.003 | (−1.59) |
TANGit | 0.084*** | (5.45) | −0.006*** | (−3.89) |
OPER_CCit | 0.027*** | (4.83) | −0.004*** | (−3.53) |
Qit | 0.012** | (2.53) | 0.001 | (1.22) |
Constant | 0.255*** | (4.83) | 0.096*** | (12.69) |
Observations | 1,439 | 1,017 | ||
F | 14.5*** | 28.6*** | ||
R2 | 0.280 | 0.431 |
Note(s): Entropy balancing regression model. Over-(under)investment in labor (OVER_LABit or UNDER_LABit) in firm i occurs when the ratio of the number of employees at the end of financial year t to the annual sales of firm i during year t is greater (lower) than the ratio of the total number of employees of all firms in the same industry sector in year t to the total annual sales for all firms in the same industry sector in year t. In the sub-sample of over-investment in labor, a higher (lower) positive number indicates a higher (lower) over-investment in labor. For ease of interpretation, the negative signs of the sub-sample for under-investment in labor are multiplied by −1 to obtain a positive number. Hence, a higher (lower) positive number indicates a higher (lower) under-investment in labor. The presence of PCBsit is a dummy variable set to 1 if firm i in year t has politically-connected board member(s) and zero (0) otherwise. Columns 1 and 2 report the OVER_LAB regression coefficients and t-values in parentheses, columns 3–4 report the UNDER_LAB regression coefficients and t-values in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1% levels, respectively (two-tailed). The definitions of variables are presented in Appendix
Source(s): Table 7 by authors
Additional test: THE relationship between politically-connected boards (PCBs) and over-investment in labor (OVER_LAB) and under-investment in labor (UNDER_LAB) after incorporating additional control variables related to board characteristics in the main regression
OVER_LAB | UNDER_LAB | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
Coefficient | t-values | Coefficient | t-values | |
#1 | #2 | #3 | #4 | |
PCBsit | −0.050** | (−2.17) | −0.001 | (−0.01) |
AVG_BOARD_AGEit | −0.001 | (−0.83) | −0.001 | (−0.48) |
AVG_BOARD_EDUit | 0.006 | (0.29) | −0.001 | (−0.47) |
INDEP_SBit | 0.023 | (0.34) | −0.007 | (−0.60) |
FEM_BOARDit | 0.002** | (2.54) | −0.001 | (−0.21) |
TOP5it | −0.046 | (−0.87) | 0.011 | (1.47) |
LEVit | −0.116** | (−2.06) | 0.008 | (1.13) |
ROAit | −0.415*** | (−4.03) | −0.013 | (−0.77) |
DPRit | −0.026 | (−1.63) | −0.002 | (−0.72) |
TANGit | 0.082*** | (2.83) | −0.007** | (−2.01) |
OPER_CCit | 0.025** | (2.17) | −0.004* | (−1.81) |
Qit | 0.012* | (1.68) | 0.001 | (1.01) |
Constant | 0.309* | (1.96) | 0.106*** | (5.57) |
Industry FE | Yes | Yes | ||
Year FE | Yes | Yes | ||
Observations | 1,396 | 991 | ||
F | 5.47*** | 10.67*** | ||
R2 | 0.287 | 0.428 |
Note(s): Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regression model, t-statistics calculated based on the robust standard errors clustered at firm-level. Over-(under)investment in labor (OVER_LABit or UNDER_LABit) in firm i occurs when the ratio of the number of employees at the end of financial year t to the annual sales of firm i during year t is greater (lower) than the ratio of the total number of employees of all firms in the same industry sector in year t to the total annual sales for all firms in the same industry sector in year t. In the sub-sample of over-investment in labor, a higher (lower) positive number indicates a higher (lower) over-investment in labor. For ease of interpretation, the negative signs of the sub-sample for under-investment in labor are multiplied by −1 to obtain a positive number. Hence, a higher (lower) positive number indicates a higher (lower) under-investment in labor. The presence of PCBsit is a dummy variable set to 1 if firm i in year t has politically-connected board member(s) and zero (0) otherwise. Columns 1 and 2 report the OVER_LAB regression coefficients and t-values in parentheses, columns 3–4 report the UNDER_LAB regression coefficients and t-values in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1% levels, respectively (two-tailed). The definitions of variables are presented in Appendix
Source(s): Table 8 by authors
Additional test: the effects of politically-connected boards (PCBs) on over-investment in labor (OVER_LAB) and under-investment in labor (UNDER_LAB) using the alternative proxies for over-(under)-investment in labor
Mean (average) industry | Median industry | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
OVER_LAB | UNDER_LAB | OVER_LAB | UNDER_LAB | |||||
Coefficient | t-values | Coefficient | t-values | Coefficient | t-values | Coefficient | t-values | |
#1 | #2 | #3 | #4 | #5 | #6 | #7 | #8 | |
PCBsit | −0.051** | (−2.46) | −0.001 | (−0.22) | −0.055** | (−2.52) | 0.001 | (0.21) |
TOP5it | −0.039 | (−0.84) | 0.007 | (1.08) | −0.056 | (−1.13) | 0.015** | (1.92) |
LEVit | −0.117** | (−2.12) | 0.007 | (1.21) | −0.090* | (−1.66) | 0.011 | (1.28) |
ROAit | −0.38*** | (−3.51) | −0.017 | (−1.11) | −0.348*** | (−3.21) | 0.001 | (0.01) |
DPRit | −0.033** | (−1.98) | 0.001 | (0.04) | −0.034** | (−2.03) | −0.004 | (−1.17) |
TANGit | 0.069** | (2.22) | −0.008*** | (−2.61) | 0.067** | (2.11) | −0.002 | (−0.56) |
OPER_CCit | 0.031*** | (2.73) | −0.002 | (−1.25) | 0.026** | (2.31) | −0.001 | (−0.40) |
Qit | 0.014* | (1.80) | 0.001 | (0.86) | 0.012* | (1.64) | 0.001 | (0.94) |
Constant | 0.274*** | (2.97) | 0.085*** | (7.84) | 0.245** | (2.65) | 0.122*** | (6.67) |
Industry FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | ||||
Year FE | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | ||||
Observations | 1,273 | 1,183 | 1,191 | 1,191 | ||||
F | 5.88*** | 15.48*** | 4.17*** | 12.51*** | ||||
R2 | 0.302 | 0.402 | 0.254 | 0.418 |
Note(s): Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regression model, t-statistics calculated based on the robust standard errors clustered at firm-level. Over-(under-)investment in labor in firm i occurs when the ratio of the number of employees at the end of financial year t to the annual sales of firm i during year t is greater (lower) than the mean (median) value of this ratio for all firms in the same industry sector in year t. In the sub-sample of over-investment in labor, a higher (lower) positive number indicates a higher (lower) over-investment in labor. For ease of interpretation, the negative signs of the sub-sample for under-investment in labor are multiplied by −1 to obtain a positive number. Hence, a higher (lower) positive number indicates a higher (lower) under-investment in labor. The presence of PCBsit is a dummy variable set to 1 if firm i in year t has politically-connected board member(s) and zero (0) otherwise. Columns 1, 2, 5 and 6 report the OVER_LAB regression coefficients and t-values in parentheses, columns 3, 4, 7 and 8 report the UNDER_LAB regression coefficients and t-values in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1% levels, respectively (two-tailed). The definitions of variables are presented in Appendix
Source(s): Table 9 by authors
Additional test: The effects of politically-connected boards (PCBs) on over-investment in labor (OVER_LAB) and under-investment in labor (UNDER_LAB) using a continuous variable-the number of politically-connected board members on the boards as an alternative proxy for PCBs
OVER_LAB | UNDER_LAB | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
Coefficient | t-values | Coefficient | t-values | |
#1 | #2 | #3 | #4 | |
NUMPCBsit | −0.048** | (−2.29) | −0.001 | (−0.29) |
TOP5it | −0.032 | (−0.66) | 0.008 | (1.15) |
LEVit | −0.117** | (−2.14) | 0.007 | (0.92) |
ROAit | −0.406*** | (−3.83) | −0.017 | (−1.01) |
DPRit | −0.034** | (−2.24) | −0.002 | (−0.79) |
TANGit | 0.086*** | (2.89) | −0.007** | (−1.98) |
OPER_CCit | 0.029** | (2.52) | −0.004** | (−2.15) |
Qit | 0.014* | (1.81) | 0.001 | (0.99) |
Constant | 0.247** | (2.48) | 0.100*** | (7.32) |
Industry FE | Yes | Yes | ||
Year FE | Yes | Yes | ||
Observations | 1,439 | 1,017 | ||
F | 5.14*** | 10.65*** | ||
R2 | 0.2687 | 0.4205 |
Note(s): Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regression model, t-statistics calculated based on the robust standard errors clustered at firm-level. Over-(under)investment in labor (OVER_LABit or UNDER_LABit) in firm i occurs when the ratio of the number of employees at the end of financial year t to the annual sales of firm i during year t is greater (lower) than the ratio of the total number of employees of all firms in the same industry sector in year t to the total annual sales for all firms in the same industry sector in year t. In the sub-sample of over-investment in labor, a higher (lower) positive number indicates a higher (lower) over-investment in labor. For ease of interpretation, the negative signs of the sub-sample for under-investment in labor are multiplied by −1 to obtain a positive number. Hence, a higher (lower) positive number indicates a higher (lower) under-investment in labor. The number of politically-connected members on the boards of firm i in year t (NUMPCBsit) is a continuous variable. Columns 1 and 2 report the OVER_LAB regression coefficients and t-values in parentheses, columns 3–4 report the UNDER_LAB regression coefficients and t-values in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1% levels, respectively (two-tailed). The definitions of variables are presented in Appendix
Source(s): Table 10 by authors
Channel analysis: the mediation variable is the dividend payout ratio (DPR)
First step | Second step | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
DPR | OVER_LAB | |||
Coefficient | t-values | Coefficient | t-values | |
#1 | #2 | #3 | #4 | |
PCBsit | 0.058*** | (2.61) | −0.048** | (−2.29) |
DPRit | −0.034** | (−2.24) | ||
TOP5it | 0.084 | (1.41) | −0.032 | (−0.66) |
LEVit | −0.094* | (−1.76) | −0.117** | (−2.14) |
ROAit | 1.147*** | (6.26) | −0.406*** | (−3.83) |
TANGit | −0.019 | (−0.74) | 0.086*** | (2.89) |
OPER_CCit | −0.029** | (−2.07) | 0.029** | (2.52) |
Qit | 0.023** | (2.57) | 0.014* | (1.81) |
Constant | 0.209** | (2.26) | 0.247** | (2.48) |
Industry FE | Yes | Yes | ||
Year FE | Yes | Yes | ||
Observations | 2,456 | 1,439 | ||
F | 9.00*** | 5.14*** | ||
R2 | 0.176 | 0.269 |
Note(s): Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regression model, t-statistics calculated based on the robust standard errors clustered at firm-level. DPRit is the dividend payout ratio of firm i in year t. We use DPRit as the mediation effect for the channel analysis using two-step regression model as suggested by Liang et al. (2024). The presence of PCBsit is a dummy variable set to 1 if firm i in year t has politically-connected board member(s) and zero (0) otherwise. Columns 1, 2, 3 and 4 report the DPR and OVER_LAB regression coefficients and t-values in parentheses, respectively. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1% levels, respectively (two-tailed). The definitions of variables are presented in Appendix
Source(s): Table 11 by authors
Definitions of variables
Variable | Definition |
---|---|
Dependent variable | |
OVER_LABit | Over-investment in labor (OVER_LAB) in firm i occurs when the ratio of the number of employees at the end of financial year t to the annual sales of firm i during year t is greater than the ratio of the total number of employees of all firms in the same industry sector in year t to the total annual sales for all firms in the same industry sector in year t (Mishina et al., 2004) |
UNDER_LABit | Under-investment in labor (UNDER_LAB) in firm i occurs when the ratio of the number of employees at the end of financial year t to the annual sales of firm i during year t is lower than the ratio of the total number of employees of all firms in the same industry sector in year t to the total annual sales for all firms in the same industry sector in year t (Mishina et al., 2004). For ease of interpretation, the negative signs of the sub-sample for under-investment in labor are multiplied by −1 to obtain a positive number. Hence, a higher (lower) positive number indicates a higher (lower) under-investment in labor |
Explanatory variable | |
PCBsit | PCBs (Politically-connected boards): Dummy variable set to one (1) if firm i in year t has politically-connected board member(s) (PCBs) and zero (0) otherwise (Faccio, 2006; Chaney et al., 2011; Arifin et al., 2020)) |
NUMPCBsit | NUMPCBsit is the number of politically-connected members on the boards of firm i in year t, which is a continuous variable |
Moderating variable | |
SB_TENRit | Supervisory board’s optimal tenure: Dummy variable with the value of one (1) if the average SB tenure of firm i in year t is between five and ten years, and zero (0) otherwise. We also use eight to eleven years as SB optimal tenure (Huang & Hilary, 2018) |
Control variables | |
TOP5it | Ownership concentration: percentage of shares held by five largest shareholders of firm i in year t (Fan & Wong, 2002; Leuz, Nanda, & Wysocki, 2003; Firth, Fung, & Rui, 2007) |
LEVit | Leverage: Total debt scaled by total assets of firm i in year t (Ang et al., 2000; Harvey, Lins, & Roper, 2004; Garanina & Kaikova, 2016) |
ROAit | Return on assets: Net income scaled by the total asset of firm i in year t s (Cronqvist & Nilsson, 2003; Dey, 2008; Choy, Gul, & Yao, 2011) |
DPRit | Dividend pay-out ratio: Total dividend payments scaled by net income of firm i in year t (Su et al., 2014) |
TANGit | Asset tangibility ratio: Net fixed assets (Net value of property, plant, and equipment after depreciation) scaled by total assets of firm i in year t (Harvey et al., 2004; He & Luo, 2018) |
OPER_CCit | Operating Cycle: Natural logarithm of the operating cycle of firm i in year t (Days Inventory + Days Account Receivable) |
Qit | Tobin’s q: Book value of total assets minus book value of equity plus market value of equity scaled by book value of total assets of firm i in year t (Cronqvist & Nilsson, 2003; Dey, 2008; Choy et al., 2011; Aktas, Andreou, Karasamani, & Philip, 2019) |
∑INDUSTRYi | It represents industry fixed effect |
∑YEARt | It represents year fixed effect |
Instrumental variables | |
AVG_BOARD_AGEit | Average age of board members of firm i in year t (An et al., 2016; Xu et al., 2016) |
AVG_BOARD_EDUit | Average education level of board members of firm i in year t Scoring method: 1-up to high school, 2-Bachelor degree, 3-Master degree, 4-Doctorate degree (An et al., 2016) |
Other variables | |
INDEP_SBit | The proportion of independent members on the supervisory board of firm i in year t (El Ammari, 2023) |
FEM_BOARDit | The proportion of female members on the boards of firm i in year t (Proença et al., 2020) |
Source(s): Appendix by authors
Notes
Investment in labor enables a firm to formulate a distinctive competitive strategy. However, this strategy also entails significant expenses related to labor adjustments. A firm often encounters challenges in recruiting individuals who align with the firm’s requirements. Consequently, the turnover of the existing labor force results in elevated expenditures for recruitment, training, and productivity losses. Given that cash reserves serve as a safeguard against various risks, heightened investment in labor prompts companies to hold a greater amount of precautionary cash (Huang, Pan, Zhu, & Chen, 2023). In an effort to mitigate these costs and/or expenditures, the company often minimises labor adjustments and maintains a stable level of labor force.
Aleksey (2009) states that “Managers at low levels of moral development are more likely to behave like agents, while managers at higher levels of moral development are more likely to behave like stewards” (p. 239). Stewardship theory suggests that when managers see themselves as stewards, they aim for trust and good reputation therefore they are more likely to maximize the firm’s value (Zhang et al., 2018; Eddleston & Kellermanns, 2007; Tosi et al., 2003).
Yap et al. (2020) state that “Indonesian Company Law confers the Board of Commissioners with a statutory right to (1) access the premises of the company; (2) access the company's documents and records; (3) inspect the company's accounts and financial statements; and (4) require the Board of Directors to provide the Board of Commissioners with further information in relation to the affairs of the company at any time”. All these rules are made in good faith with the intention of strengthening the role of BOC in overseeing the BOD and guiding the management to achieve the firm’s goals.
In this context, entrenchment refers to a situation where board members may act in their own interest or derive benefits at the expense of shareholders or investors.
Industry distribution is based on Indonesia Stock Exchange (IDX)’s industry classification which is derived from Indonesia Business Classification (IBS) published by Central of Agency on Statistics Indonesia/Badan Pusat Statistik (BPS). IBS is constructed by BPS using International Standard Industrial Classification (ISIC).
Mishina et al. (2004) use this model to measure over-(under)-investment in labor of 112 publicly listed firms. We adopt their model since it is appropriate with the Indonesian data which comprises260 publicly listed firms.
Our untabulated results using Heckman treatment effect-2SLS also confirm the same findings for H3.
Our untabulated results using entropy balancing also confirm the same findings for H3.
Declaration: We (all authors) do not have conflict of interest in the research.
Sample distribution
Panel A: Sample selection process | ||
---|---|---|
Description | Firm | Firm years |
IDX listed firms/observations from 2010 to 2019 | 413 | 4,130 |
Less | ||
financial firms/observations* | (68) | (680) |
utility firms/observations | (2) | (20) |
firms/observations with missing/incomplete data | (66) | (660) |
firms/observations with negative equities** | (17) | (170) |
firms/observations with missing data for control variable(s) | (144) | |
Final sample firms/observations | 260 | 2,456 |
Note(s): *Firms with JASICA code 8, which include Banks (81), Multi-finance (82), Securities (83), Insurance (84) and others (89) **Either in a single period or multiple periods between 2010 and 2019 |
Panel B: Industry distribution | ||
---|---|---|
Industry sector | Number of firms | % |
Agriculture | 13 | 5.00 |
Mining | 25 | 9.62 |
Metal | 11 | 4.23 |
Forestry and livestock | 13 | 5.00 |
Other basic industry | 21 | 8.08 |
Miscellaneous manufacturing industry | 24 | 9.23 |
Consumer good manufacturers | 29 | 11.15 |
Property | 46 | 17.69 |
Telecommunication and Transportation | 18 | 6.92 |
Hospitality (services) | 14 | 5.38 |
Trading | 21 | 8.08 |
Other services industry | 25 | 9.62 |
Total | 260 | 100% |
Note(s): Industry distribution is based on Indonesia Stock Exchange (IDX)’s industry classification which is derived from Indonesia Business Classification (IBS) published by Central of Agency on Statistics Indonesia/Badan Pusat Statistik (BPS). IBS is constructed by BPS using International Standard Industrial Classification (ISIC)
Source(s): Table 1 by authors
References
Agrawal, A., & Knoeber, C. R. (2001). Do some outside directors play a political role?. The Journal of Law and Economics, 44(1), 179–198. doi: 10.1086/320271.
Aksin, O. Z., Cakan, N., Karaesmen, F., & Omeci, E. L. (2015). Flexibility structure and capacity design with human resouces considerations. Production and Operations Management, 24(7), 1086–1100. doi: 10.1111/poms.12333.
Aktas, N., Andreou, P. C., Karasamani, I., & Philip, D. (2019). CEO duality, agency costs, and internal capital allocation efficiency. British Journal of Management, 30(2), 473–493. doi: 10.1111/1467-8551.12277.
Aleksey, M. (2009). Agents or stewards? Linking managerial behavior and moral development. Journal of Business Ethics, 90(2), 239–249. doi: 10.1007/s10551-009-0039-7.
Alves, I., & Lourenço, S. M. (2023). Subjective performance evaluation and managerial work outcomes. Accounting and Business Research, 53(2), 127–157. doi: 10.1080/00014788.2021.1959292.
Amah, O. E. (2022). The role of political prudenc and political skill in the political will and political behavior relationships. Journal of Business Ethics, 176(2), 341–355. doi: 10.1007/s10551-020-04696-x.
An, H., Chen, Y., Luo, D., & Zhang, T. (2016). Political uncertainty and corporate investment: Evidence from China. Journal of Corporate Finance, 36, 174–189. doi: 10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2015.11.003.
Anderson, R. C., & Reeb, D. M. (2003). Founding family ownership and firm performance: Evidence from the S&P 500. Journal of Finance, 58(3), 1301–1328. doi: 10.1111/1540-6261.00567.
Anderson, R., Mansi, C. S. A., & Reeb, D. M. (2004). Board characteristics, accounting report integrity, and the cost of debt. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 37(3), 315–42. doi: 10.1016/j.jacceco.2004.01.004.
Ang, J. S., Cole, R. A., & Lin, J. W. (2000). Agency costs and ownership structure. The Journal of Finance, 55(1), 81–106. doi: 10.1111/0022-1082.00201.
Arifin, T., Hasan, I., & Kabir, R. (2020). Transactional and relational approaches to political connections and the cost of debt. Journal of Corporate Finance, 65, 1–16. doi: 10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2020.101768.
Azadegan, A., Patel, P. C., & Parida, V. (2013). Operational slack and venture survival. Production and Operation Management, 22(1), 1–18. doi: 10.1111/j.1937-5956.2012.01361.x.
Bacon, J., & Brown, J. K. (1975). Corporate directorship prices, role, selection and legal status of the board. Conference Board report no. 646. New York.
Bae, K. -H., Kang, J. -K., & Wang, J. (2011). Employee treatment and firm leverage: A test of the stakeholder theory of capital structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 100(1), 130–153. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.10.019.
Batta, G., Ricardo, S. H., & March, W. (2014). Political connections and accounting quality under high expropriation risk. European Accounting Review, 23(4), 485–517. doi: 10.1080/09638180.2014.906316.
Beasley, M. S. (1996). An empirical analysis of the relation between the board of director composition and financial statement fraud. The Accounting Review, 71(4), 443–65, Available from: https://www.jstor.org/stable/248566
Becker, B. E., & Huselid, M. A. (2006). Strategic human resources management: Where do we go from here?. Journal of Management, 32(6), 898–925. doi: 10.1177/0149206306293668.
Belot, F., Ginglinger, E., Slovin, M. B., & Sushka, M. E. (2014). Freedom of choice between unitary and two-tier boards: An empirical analysis. Journal of Financial Economics, 112(3), 364–385. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2014.02.011.
Ben-Amar, W. P., & André, P. (2006). Separation of ownership from control and acquiring firm performance: The case of family ownership in Canada. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 33(3-4), 517–543. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-5957.2006.00613.x.
Bertrand, M., & Mullainathan, S. (2003). Enjoying the quiet life? Corporate governance and managerial preferences. Journal of Political Economy, 111(5), 1043–1075. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-5957.2006.00613.x.
Bona-Sánchez, C., Pérez-Alemán, J., & Santana-Martín, D. J. (2014). Politically-connected firms and earnings informativeness in the controlling versus minority shareholders context: European evidence. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 22(4), 330–346. doi: 10.1111/corg.12064.
Boon, C., Eckardt, R., Lepak, D. P., & Boselie, P. (2017). Integrating strategic human capital and strategic human resource management. The International Journal of Human Resource Management, 29(1), 34–67. doi: 10.1080/09585192.2017.1380063.
Butler, A. W., Fauver, L., & Mortal, S. (2009). Corruption, political connections, and municipal finance. The Review of Financial Studies, 22(7), 2873–2905. doi: 10.1093/rfs/hhp010.
Cao, Z., & Rees, W. (2020). Do employee-friendly firms invest more efficiently? Evidence from labor investment efficiency. Journal of Corporate Finance, 65, 101744. doi: 10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2020.101744.
Chaney, P. K., Faccio, M., & Parsley, D. (2011). The quality of accounting information in politically connected firms. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 51(1-2), 58–76. doi: 10.1016/j.jacceco.2010.07.003.
Chang, S. J. (2003). Ownership structure, expropriation, and performance of group-affiliated companies in Korea. Academy of Management Journal, 46(2), 238–253. doi:10.5465/30040617.
Chen, H., Kacperczyk, M., & Ortiz-Molina, H. (2011). Labor unions, operating flexibility, and the cost of equity. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 46(1), 25–58. doi: 10.1017/S0022109010000645.
Chen, S., Sun, Z., Tang, S., & Wu, D. (2011). Government intervention and investment efficiency: Evidence from China. Journal of Corporate Finance, 17(2), 259–271. doi: 10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2010.08.004.
Chen, J., Tong, J. Y., Wang, W., & Zhang, F. (2019). The economic consequences of labor unionization: Evidence from stock price crash risk. Journal of Business Ethics, 157(3), 775–796. doi: 10.1007/s10551-017-3686-0.
Cherkasova, V., & Ivanova, A. (2019). Do political connections influence investment efficiency in Russian companies?. Journal of Corporate Finance Research, 13(2), 36–49. doi: 10.17323/j.jcfr.2073-0438.13.2.2019.36-49.
Choi, S. L., Heo, W., Cho, S. H., & Lee, P. (2020). The links between job insecurity, financial well-being and financial stress: A moderated mediation model. International Journal of Consumer Studies, 44(4), 353–360. doi: 10.1111/ijcs.12571.
Choy, H., Gul, F. A., & Yao, J. (2011). Does political economy reduce agency costs? Some evidence from dividend policies around the world. Journal of Empirical Finance, 18(1), 16–35. doi: 10.1016/j.jempfin.2010.10.001.
Chu, T., Haw, I. M., Ho, S. S. M., & Zhang, X. (2020). Labor protection, ownership concentration, and cost of equity capital: International evidence. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting, 54(4), 1351–1387. doi: 10.1007/s11156-019-00828-1.
Chu, J., Gupta, A., & Livne, G. (2021). Pay regulation–is more better?. Accounting and Business Research, 51(1), 1–35. doi: 10.1080/00014788.2020.1815515.
Claessens, S. (2006). Corporate governance and development. The World Bank Research Observer, 21(1), 91–122. doi: 10.1093/wbro/lkj004.
Claessens, S., Djankov, S., Fan, J. P. H., & Lang, L. P. H. (2002). Disentangling the incentive and entrenchment effects of large shareholdings. Journal of Finance, 57(6), 2741–2771. doi: 10.1111/1540-6261.00511.
Cronqvist, H., & Nilsson, M. (2003). Agency costs of controlling minority shareholders. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 38(4), 695–719. doi: 10.2307/4126740.
David, P., O'Brien, J. P., Yoshikawa, T., & Delios, A. (2010). Do shareholders or stakeholders appropriate the rents from corporate diversification? The influence of ownership structure. Academy of Management Journal, 53(3), 636–654. doi: 10.5465/amj.2010.51469005.
De Stefano, F., Bonet, R., & Camuffo, A. (2019). Does losing temporary workers matter? The effects of planned turnover on replacements and unit performance. Academy of Management Annals, 62(4), 979–1002. doi: 10.5465/amj.2017.0291.
Dey, A. (2008). Corporate governance and agency conflicts. Journal of Accounting Research, 46(5), 1143–1181. doi: 10.1111/j.1475-679X.2008.00301.x.
Dieleman, M., & Sachs, W. M. (2008). Coevolution of institutions and corporations in emerging economies: How the Salim group morphed into an institution of Suharto's Crony Regime. Journal of Management Studies, 45(7), 1274–1300. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6486.2008.00793.x.
Dixit, R. K., & Pindyck, R. S. (2012). Investment under uncertainty, Princenton: Princenton University Press.
Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2010). Disclosure by politicians. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2, 179–209. doi: 10.1257/app.2.2.179.
Drábek, J., Lorincová, S., & Javorčíková, J. (2017). Investing in human capital as a key factor for development of enterprises. in L. Mura (Ed.), Issues of Human Resource Management, open-access, peer-reviewed. doi: 10.5772/67741.
Duchin, R., & Sosyura, D. (2012). The politics of government investment. Journal of Financial Economics, 106(1), 24–48. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2012.04.009.
Eddleston, K. A., & Kellermanns, F. W. (2007). Destructive and productive family relationships: A stewardship theory perspective. Journal of Business Venturing, 22(4), 545–65. doi: 10.1016/j.jbusvent.2006.06.004.
El Ammari, A. (2023). Does political connection affect corporate financial performance? The moderating role of directors’ financial expertise. Journal of Financial Reporting and Accounting, 21(5), 1073–1099. doi: 10.1108/JFRA-08-2021-0257.
El Nayal, O., Van Oosterhout, J., & Van Essen, M. (2021). Ties that bind and grind? Investor reactions to politician appointments to corporate boards. Journal of Management, 47(2), 456–497. doi: 10.1177/0149206319869440.
Faccio, M. (2006). Politically connected firms. American Economic Review, 96(1), 369–386. doi: 10.1257/000282806776157704.
Fan, H., & Chen, L. (2022). Political connections, business strategy and tax aggressiveness: Evidence from China. China Accounting and Finance Review, 25(2), 125–144. doi: 10.1108/CAFR-07-2022-0086.
Fan, J. P. H., & Wong, T. J. (2002). Corporate ownership structure and the informativeness of accounting earnings in East Asia. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 33(3), 401–425. doi: 10.1016/S0165-4101(02)00047-2.
Ferguson, K. L., & Reio, T. G. (2010). Human resource management systems and firm performance. Journal of Management Development, 29(5), 471–494. doi: 10.1108/02621711011039231.
Firth, M., Fung, P. M., & Rui, O. M. (2007). Ownership, two-tier board structure, and the informativeness of earnings–Evidence from China. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 26(4), 463–496. doi: 10.1016/j.jaccpubpol.2007.05.004.
Fisman, R. (2001). Estimating the value of political connections. The American Economic Review, 91(4), 1095–1102. doi: 10.1257/aer.91.4.1095.
Franzoni, F. (2009). Underinvestment vs overinvestment: Evidence from price reactions to pension contributions. Journal of Financial Economics, 92(3), 491–518. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2008.06.004.
Gao, R., Martin, G., Hu, H. W., & Lu, J. W. (2023). Why embrace a double-edged sword? A behavioral theory of board political capital building. Strategic Organization, 21(4), 933–960. doi: 10.1177/14761270221134985.
Garanina, T., & Kaikova, E. (2016). Corporate governance mechanisms and agency costs: Cross-country analysis. Corporate Governance, 16(2), 347–360. doi: 10.1108/cg-04-2015-0043.
Ghaly, M., Dang, V. A., & Stathopoulos, K. (2020). Institutional investors’ horizons and corporate employment decisions. Journal of Corporate Finance, 64, 101634. doi: 10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2020.101634.
Gilson, R. J. (2007). Controlling family shareholders in developing countries: Anchoring relational exchange. Stanford Law Review, 60, 633–55. doi: 10.2139/ssrn.957895.
Golden, B. R., & Zajac, E. J. (2001). When will boards influence strategy? Inclination × power= strategic change. Strategic Management Journal, 22(12), 1087–1111. doi: 10.1002/smj.202.
Goldman, E., Rocholl, J., & Jongil, S. (2009). Do politically-connected boards affect firm Value?. The Review of Financial Studies, 22(6), 2331–2360. doi: 10.1093/rfs/hhn088.
González-Bailon, S., Jennings, W., & Lodge, M. (2013). Politics in the boardroom: Corporate pay, networks and recruitment of former parliamentarians, ministers and civil servants in Britain. Political Studies, 61(4), 850–873. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9248.2012.00994.x.
Habib, A., & Hasan, M. M. (2021). Business strategy and labor investment efficiency. International Review of Finance, 21(1), 58–96. doi: 10.1111/irfi.12254.
Hainmueller, J. (2012). Entropy balancing for causal effects: A multivariate reweighting method to produce balanced samples in observational studies. Political Analysis, 20(1), 25–46. doi: 10.1093/pan/mpr025.
Hainmueller, J., & Xu, Y. (2013). Ebalance: A stata package for entropy balancing. Journal of Statistical Software, 54. doi: 10.2139/ssrn.1943090.
Hamermesh, D. S. (1995). Labor demand and the source of adjustment costs. Economics Journal, 105(430), 620–634. doi: 10.2307/2235021.
Harianto, S. (2020). Political connections, internal conflicts of interest, earnings management, and investment inefficiency: Additional Evidence from Indonesia, Kingston upon Hull: University of Hull.
Harvey, C. R., Lins, K. V., & Roper, A. H. (2004). The effect of capital structure when expected agency costs are extreme. Journal of Financial Economics, 74(1), 3–30. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2003.07.003.
He, W., & Luo, J. H. (2018). Agency problems in firms with an even number of directors: Evidence from China. Journal of Banking and Finance, 93, 139–150. doi: 10.1016/j.jbankfin.2018.06.006.
Holderness, C. G., & Sheehanm, D. P. (1988). The role of majority shareholders in publicly held corporations: An exploratory analysis. Journal of Financial Economics, 20, 317–346. doi: 10.1016/0304-405X(88)90049-9.
Huang, S., & Hilary, G. (2018). Zombie board: Board tenure and firm performance. Journal of Accounting Research, 56(4), 1285–1329. doi: 10.1111/1475-679X.12209.
Huang, T., Pan, Y., Zhu, K., & Chen, X. (2023). Human resource heterogeneity, hold-up and firm cash holdings. China Accounting and Finance Review, 25(1), 54–74. doi: 10.1108/CAFR-09-2022-0105.
International Finance Corporation & Indonesia Financial Services Authority (IFC& IFSA) (2014). The Indonesia corporate governance manual. In IFC Advisory Services in Indonesia (1st Edition).
International Finance Corporation & Indonesia Financial Services Authority (IFC& IFSA) (2018). The Indonesia corporate governance manual. In IFC Advisory Services in Indonesia (2nd Edition).
Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Agency costs and the theory of the firm. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305–360. doi: 10.1016/0304-405x(76)90026-x.
Jia, N. (2017). Should directors have term limits?-Evidence from corporate innnovation. European Accounting Review, 26(4), 755–785. doi: 10.1080/09638180.2016.1199321.
Joni, J., Ahmed, K., & Hamilton, J. (2020). Politically connected boards, family and business group affiliations, and cost of capital: Evidence from Indonesia. The British Accounting Review, 52(3), 100878. doi: 10.1016/j.bar.2019.100878.
Jung, B., Lee, W. J., & Weber, D. P. (2014). Financial reporting quality andlLabor investment Efficiency. Contemporary Accounting Research, 31(4), 1047–1076. doi: 10.1111/1911-3846.12053.
Jungmann, C. (2006). The effectiveness of corporate governance in one-tier and two-tier board systems. European Company and Financial Law Review, 3(4), 426–474. doi: 10.1515/ECFR.2006.019.
Kennedy, P. (2003). A guide to econometrics (5th ed.). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Khalil, M., Harianto, S., & Guney, Y. (2022). Do political connections reduce earnings management?. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting, 59(1), 273–310. doi: 10.1007/s11156-022-01062-y.
Khedmati, M., Sualihu, M. A., & Yawson, A. (2020). CEO-director ties and labor investment efficiency. Journal of Corporate Finance, 65(1), 101492. doi: 10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2019.101492.
Kim, C., & Zhang, L. (2016). Corporate political connections and tax aggressiveness. Contemporary Accounting Research, 33(1), 78–114. doi: 10.1111/1911-3846.12150.
Kim, C., Pantzalis, C., & Park, J. (2012). Political geography and stock returns: The value and risk implications of proximity to political power. Journal of Financial Economics, 106(1), 196–228. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2012.05.007.
Kor, Y. Y., & Sundaramurthy, C. (2009). Experience-based human capital and social capital of outside directors. Journal of Management, 35(4), 981–1006. doi: 10.1177/0149206308321551.
Kraft, A., Leone, A. J., & Wasley, C. E. (2007). Regression-based tests of the market pricing of accounting numbers: The Mishkin test and ordinary least squares. Journal of Accounting Research, 45(5), 1081–1114. doi: 10.1111/j.1475-679X.2007.00261.x.
Krueger, A. O. (1974). The political economy of the rent-seeking society. The American Economic Review, 64, 291–303.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (2000). Agency problems and dividend policies around the world. Journal of Finance, 55, 1–33. doi: 10.1111/0022-1082.00199.
Lee, K. Y., & Mo, K. (2020). Do analysts improve labor investment efficiency?. Journal of Contemporary Accounting and Economics, 16(3), 100213. doi: 10.1016/j.jcae.2020.100213.
Leuz, C., Nanda, D., & Wysocki, P. D. (2003). Earnings management and investor protection: An international comparison. Journal of Financial Economics, 69(3), 505–527. doi: 10.1016/S0304-405X(03)00121-1.
Li, N., & Wahid, A. S. (2018). Director tenure diversity and board monitoring effectiveness. Contemporary Accounting Research, 35(3), 1363–1394. doi: 10.1111/1911-3846.12332.
Li, W., He, A., Lan, H., & Yiu, D. (2012). Political connections and corporate diversification in emerging economies: Evidence from China. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 29(3), 799–818. doi: 10.1007/s10490-011-9265-5.
Li, J., Xia, J., & Zajac, E. J. (2018). On the duality of political and economic stakeholder influence on firm innovation performance: Theory and evidence from Chinese firms. Strategic Management Journal, 39(1), 193–216. doi: 10.1002/smj.2697.
Liang, S., Fu, R., & Jiang, Y. (2024). Independent directors’ status and R&D: A study based on Chinese cultural background. China Accounting and Finance Review, 26(1), 102–133. doi: 10.1057/9781137341570_8.
Liedong, T. A. (2021). Responsible firm behaviour in political markets: Judging the ethicality of corporate political activity in weak institutional enviroments. Journal of Business Ethics, 172(2), 325–345. doi: 10.1007/s10551-020-04503-7.
Lin, T., Tsai, H., & Yao, F. (2021). The dividend payout policy in Chinese listed firms. Journal of Accounting, Finance and Management Strategy, 16(2), 56–78.
Liu, G., Xin, G., & Li, J. (2021). Making political connections work better: Information asymmetry and the development of private firms in China. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 29(6), 593–611. doi: 10.1111/corg.12390.
Luo, J., Li, X., & Chan, K. (2020). Political uncertainty and labor investment efficiency. Applied Economics, 52(43), 4677–4697. doi: 10.1080/00036846.2020.1739615.
McGuinness, P. B., Lam, K. C., & Vieito, J. P. (2015). Gender and other major board characteristics in China: Explaining corporate dividend policy and governance. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 32(4), 989–1038. doi: 10.1007/s10490-015-9443-y.
Merz, M., & Yashiv, E. (2007). Labor and the market value of the firm. The American Economic Review, 97(4), 1419–1431. doi: 10.1257/aer.97.4.1419.
Michie, J., & Sheehan, M. (2005). Business strategy, human resources, labor market flexibility and competitive advantage. The International Journal of Human Resource Management, 16(3), 445–464. doi: 10.1080/0958519042000339598.
Michiels, A., Uhlaner, L., & Dekker, J. (2017). The effect of family business professionalization on dividend payout. Journal of Small Business and Enterprise Development, 24(4), 1–13. doi: 10.1108/JSBED-01-2017-0023.
Mishina, Y., Pollock, T. G., & Porac, J. F. (2004). Are more resources always better for growth? Resource stickiness in market and product expansion. Strategic Management Journal, 25(12), 1179–1197. doi: 10.1002/smj.424.
Niessen, A., & Ruenzi, S. (2010). Political connectedness and firm performance: Evidence from Germany. German Economic Review, 11(4), 441–464. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0475.2009.00482.x.
Peng, H., Zhang, X., & Zhu, X. (2017). Political connections of the board of directors and credit financing: Evidence from Chinese private enterprises. Accounting and Finance, 57(5), 1481–1516. doi: 10.1111/acfi.12331.
Pittman, J. A., & Fortin, S. (2004). Auditor choice and the cost of debt capital for newly public firms. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 37(1), 113–136. doi: 10.1016/j.jacceco.2003.06.005.
Proença, C., Augusto, M., & Murteira, J. (2020). Political connections and banking performance: The moderating effect of gender diversity. Corporate Governance: The International Journal of Business in Society, 20(6), 1001–1028. doi: 10.1108/CG-01-2020-0018.
Sauerwald, S., Heugens, P. P. M. A. R., Turturea, R., & Essen, M. V. (2019). Are all private benefits of control ineffective? Principal-Principal conflict benefits, external governance quality anf firm performance. Journal of Management Studies, 1(4), 725–727. doi: 10.1111/joms.12420.
Scharfstein, D. S., & Stein, J. C. (1990). Herd behavior and investment. The American Economic Review, 80(3), 465–479, Available from: https://www.jstor.org/stable/2006678
Setia-Atmaja, L., Haman, J., & Tanewski, G. (2011). The role of board independence in mitigating agency problem II in Australian family firms. The British Accounting Review, 43(3), 230–246. doi: 10.1016/j.bar.2011.06.006.
Sevcenko, V., Wu, L., Kacperczyk, A., & Ethiraj, S. (2022). Surplus division between labor and capital: A review and research agenda. Academy of Management Annals, 16(1), 334–390. doi: 10.5465/annals.2019.0130.
Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1997). A survey of corporate governance. Journal of Finance, 52(2), 737–783. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1997.tb04820.x.
Stein, J. C. (2003). Chapter 2 Agency, information and corporate investment. In M. H. G. M. Constantinides, & R. M. Stulz (Eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Finance (Vol. 1, pp. 111–165). Holland: Elsevier. doi: 10.1016/s1574-0102(03)01006-9.
Stock, J. H. & Yogo, M. (2005). Testing for weak instruments in linear iv regression in Andrews
Su, Z., Fung, H., Huang, D., & Shen, C. (2014). Cash dividends, expropriation, and political connections. Evidence from China. Internatitonal Review of Economics and Finance, 29, 260–272. doi: 10.1016/j.iref.2013.05.017.
Sualihu, M. A., Rankin, M., & Haman, J. (2021). The role of equity compensation in reducing inefficient investment in labor. Journal of Corporate Finance, 66, 101788. doi: 10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2020.101788.
Sun, X. S., & Bhuiyan, M. B. U. (2020). Board tenure: A review. Journal of Corporate Accounting and Finance, 31(4), 178–196. doi: 10.1002/jcaf.22464.
Tatikonda, M. V., Terjesen, S. A., Patel, P. C., & Parida, V. (2013). The role of operational capabiliies in enhancing new venture survival: A longitudinal study. Production and Operations Management, 22(6), 1401–1415. doi: 10.1111/poms.12038.
Thompson, C. G., Kim, R. S., Aloe, A. M., & Becker, B. J. (2017). Extracting the variance inflation factor and other multicollinearity diagnostics from typical regression results. Basic and Applied Social Psychology, 39(2), 81–90. doi: 10.1080/01973533.2016.1277529.
Tosi, H. L., Brownlee, L., Silva, P., & Katz, J. P. (2003). An empirical exploration of decision-making under agency controls and stewardship structure. Journal of Management Studies, 40(8), 2053–71. doi: 10.1046/j.1467-6486.2003.00411.x.
World Economics (2024). Indonesia’s GDP compound annual growth rates. Available from: https://www.worldeconomics.com/Countries-With-Highest-Growth/Indonesia.aspx#:∼:text=Indonesia's%20Compound%20Annual%20Growth%20Rates,GDP%20data%20is%20B%20Grade (accessed 2 March 2024.
Wu, W., Wu, C., & Rui, O. M. (2012). Ownership and the value of political connections: Evidence from China. European Financial Management, 18(4), 695–729. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-036X.2010.00547.x.
Wu, J., Li, S., & Li, Z. (2013). The contingent value of CEO political connections: A study on IPO performance in China. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 30(4), 1087–1114. doi: 10.1007/s10490-012-9300-1.
Wyatt, A. (2008). What financial and non-financial information on intangibles is value-relevant? A review of the evidence. Accounting and Business Research, 38(3), 217–256. doi: 10.1080/00014788.2008.9663336.
Xu, N., Chen, Q., Xu, Y., & Chan, K. C. (2016). Political uncertainty and cash holdings: Evidence from China. Journal of Corporate Finance, 40, 276–295. doi: 10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2016.08.007.
Yap, J., Tan, D., & Lai, Z. Y. (2020). Indonesia: Corporate govenrance in Indonesia-What you need to know about the board of directors and board of commissioners. Available from: https://www.mondaq.com/shareholders/907482/corporate-governance-in-indonesia-what-you-need-to-know-about-the-board-of-directors-and-board-of-commissioners (accessed 12 March 2024).
Young, M. N., Peng, M. W., Ahlstrom, D., Bruton, G. D., & Jiang, Y. (2008). Corporate governance in emerging economies: A review of the principal–principal perspective. Journal of Management Studies, 45(1), 196–220. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6486.2007.00752.x.
Zahra, S. A., Filatotchev, I., & Wright, M. (2009). How do threshold firms sustain corporate entrepreneurship? The role of boards and absorptive capacity. Journal of Business Venturing, 24(3), 248–60. doi: 10.1016/j.jbusvent.2008.09.001.
Zhang, F., Wei, L., Yang, J., & Zhu, L. (2018). Roles of relationships between large shareholders and managers in radical innovation: A stewardship theory perspective. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 35(1), 88–105. doi: 10.1111/jpim.12376.
Further reading
Cragg, J. G., & Donald, S. G. (1993). Testing identifiability and specification in instrumental variable models. Econometric Theory, 9(2), 222–240.
Kleibergen, F. (2002). Pivotal statistics for testing structural parameters in instrumental variables regression. Econometrica, 70(5), 1781–1803. doi:10.1111/1468-0262.00353.
Kleibergen, F., & Paap, R. (2006). Generalized reduced rank tests using the singular value decomposition. Journal of Econometrics, 133(1), 97–126. doi:10.1016/j.jeconom.2005.02.011.