Abstract
Purpose
We propose a risk factor for idiosyncratic entropy and explore the relationship between this factor and expected stock returns.
Design/methodology/approach
We estimate a cross-sectional model of expected entropy that uses several common risk factors to predict idiosyncratic entropy.
Findings
We find a negative relationship between expected idiosyncratic entropy and returns. Specifically, the Carhart alpha of a low expected entropy portfolio exceeds the alpha of a high expected entropy portfolio by −2.37% per month. We also find a negative and significant price of expected idiosyncratic entropy risk using the Fama-MacBeth cross-sectional regressions. Interestingly, expected entropy helps us explain the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle that stocks with high idiosyncratic volatility earn low expected returns.
Originality/value
We propose a risk factor of idiosyncratic entropy and explore the relationship between this factor and expected stock returns. Interestingly, expected entropy helps us explain the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle that stocks with high idiosyncratic volatility earn low expected returns.
Keywords
Citation
Tavakoli Baghdadabad, M. (2024), "Expected idiosyncratic entropy", China Accounting and Finance Review, Vol. 26 No. 2, pp. 137-169. https://doi.org/10.1108/CAFR-03-2023-0021
Publisher
:Emerald Publishing Limited
Copyright © 2024, Mohammadreza Tavakoli Baghdadabad
License
Published in China Accounting and Finance Review. Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode
1. Introduction
The field of risk management has extensively studied how the risk related to the returns of assets influences investor decisions. Research by authors like Rubinstein (1973) and Kraus and Litzenberger (1976) introduced models to predict asset returns by factoring in skewness – a measure of asymmetry in returns distribution. These models effectively link the performance of individual assets to broader market risks. They demonstrate that both the shape and the shared tendencies of return distributions play a vital role in setting asset prices (for instance, Amaya, Christoffersen, Jacobs, & Vasquez, 2015). Notably, Harvey and Siddique (2000) discovered that the interplay between individual asset returns and overall market trends (co-skewness) has a measurable financial impact within the framework of market-wide decision models.
Considering the importance of shape and shared characteristics in asset pricing, its been observed that to benefit from these characteristics, some investors opt not to diversify their investments fully. This makes the unique characteristics of each asset, such as idiosyncratic volatility (IV) and idiosyncratic skewness (IS), important (e.g. Ang, Hodrick, Xing, & Zhang, 2006; Boyer, Mitton, & Vorkink, 2010). Ang, Hodrick, Xing, and Zhang (2009) discovered that IV provides key insights into the likely future performance of investments. Similarly, studies by Brunnermeier, Gollier, and Parker (2007) and Barberis and Huang (2008) show that the asymmetry in returns of individual assets (skewness) can sway investor choices. Furthermore, Boyer et al. (2010) found that investments with a high expected IS often yield lower future returns.
Generally, there are two strands in the literature: (1) studies on the role of risk-related statistical measures in influencing probability distributions, and (2) studies on the specific properties of these statistical measures. The second category reveals that many analyses overlook the erratic patterns in the residual, or leftover, returns when predicting stock performance. These erratic patterns in returns can appear in two ways: (1) as shifts in common statistical measures like standard deviation, skewness, and kurtosis, and (2) as various kinds of irregularities or disorders. It’s important to differentiate between these statistical measures and ‘entropy,’ a concept leading to different insights about forecasting residual returns. Benedetto, Giunta, and Mastroeni (2016) argue that deviations from the average return don’t always indicate unpredictability. The presence and number of irregularities significantly impact the prediction process, leading to unpredictability. They found that predictive methods are effective even with high deviations from the mean, provided the series has few irregularities. This suggests that series with fewer irregularities offer better prospects for predicting asset returns, an angle not fully explored in previous studies. Backus, Chernov, and Martin (2011) discovered that using entropy in asset pricing models improves the predictability of returns. They noted that deviations from typical distribution patterns, like sudden jumps, make entropy valuable in these models. Backus, Boyarchenko, and Chernov (2018) introduced ‘coentropy,’ which combines the effects of pricing mechanisms and cash flows. This concept emphasizes the impact of unusual market movements on risk premiums. Billio, Casarin, Costola, and Pasqualini (2016) explored systemic risk in Europe using different entropy metrics, highlighting their predictive power for financial crises. Ghosh, Julliard, and Taylor (2017) found that entropy can reveal time series details of both the Stochastic Discount Factor (SDF) and its unobservable components, overlooked by other statistical measures. They showed that entropy adds extra information to the SDFs for accurate asset return pricing. It focuses on the second-moment deviations (variance) and other measures (skewness and kurtosis), and they found that skewness and kurtosis of stock returns drive a significant portion of the entropy in their pricing model. However, combining all statistical measures in a unified pricing model captures all features of stock return variability. Calomiris and Mamaysky (2019) demonstrated that a concise summary of news, including the uniqueness (entropy) of word flow, forecasts future country-level returns, volatilities, and drawdowns. Similarly, Glasserman and Mamaysky (2019) found that the uniqueness (entropy) of word combinations can predict market outcomes, particularly when combined with sentiment analysis.
Entropy, a concept originating from both classical mechanics and information theory, plays a crucial role in understanding systems. In classical mechanics, it measures the level of uncertainty and disarray in moving systems, representing how random these systems are (Jaynes, 1965). In the realm of information theory, entropy is used to gauge the amount of information in time-based data sequences (Shannon, 1948). Shannon (1948) specifically noted that this measure indicates how uncertain a data source is when choosing what message to send, reflecting the unpredictability of the data sequence’s future behavior. In practical terms, entropy is inversely related to predictability: higher entropy means a data sequence is less predictable, while lower entropy suggests greater predictability. In our study, we apply entropy metrics to examine inconsistencies in data sequences and determine their predictability.
In this paper, we introduce a new risk factor called idiosyncratic entropy (IE) and investigate how it affects stock pricing. Although theoretical frameworks like those by Gulko (1999, 2002) suggest exploring the impact of entropy on pricing, actual studies linking IE with stock returns are more intricate. A key challenge is that entropy, unlike more stable measures such as variance, fluctuates over time, making it challenging to evaluate (Maasoumi & Racine, 2002). This necessitates using additional risk factors beyond past entropy data to accurately predict future entropy levels. Echoing the approach of Chen, Hong, and Stein (2001), we incorporate various firm-specific risk factors to forecast IE. While past entropy data is a good indicator of future levels, other firm-specific factors are crucial for predicting IE, including IV and IS – both of which are gaining attention in asset pricing. Our model also considers other vital risk factors, such as idiosyncratic kurtosis (IK, as studied by Conrad, Dittmar, & Ghysels, 2013), market beta, company size, book-to-market ratio (as per Fama & French, 1993), momentum (Carhart, 1997), co-skewness (Harvey & Siddique, 2000), liquidity (Pastor & Stambaugh, 2003), and the MAX and MIN factors introduced by Bali, Cakici, and Whitelaw (2011). This prediction model allows us to observe how expected entropy varies across different stocks and over time. Moreover, the patterns in both expected and actual entropy over time seem to mimic the episodic nature often seen in IV.
In our study using the expected entropy model, we discover a consistent and strong negative correlation between average stock returns and predicted IE. By organizing stocks into groups based on their expected IE levels, we note that stocks with lower expected IE have higher average returns than those with higher expected IE, showing a difference of −2.42% per month. This difference becomes more noticeable after accounting for risk factors. Additionally, we observe that the return (measured by Carhart alpha, 1997) of the low expected IE group surpasses that of the high IE group by −2.47% monthly. Employing the Fama and MacBeth (1973) methodology, our results validate the impact of IE on stock pricing, revealing that expected IE significantly clarifies the differences in stock returns. This influence of IE is not only statistically significant but also holds up under various validation tests. In our comparative analysis, similar to findings in Ang et al. (2006) and Boyer et al. (2010), we identify a negative relationship between IV and returns, and between IS and returns. The negative correlations observed with IV and IS lend credibility to our findings regarding IE, a relationship not previously explored in the literature. Further analysis to separate the effects of IE and IV indicates that each type of risk individually provides considerable insight into predicting stock returns.
In addition, we investigate whether changes over time in predicted entropy are linked to similar variations in the anticipated rewards for taking on entropy-related risks. Our analysis shows that the times with the most substantial negative impacts on the expected entropy reward correspond to times when the expected entropy is both high and widely varied. These are also the times when our entropy prediction model is most accurate, as shown by the high R2 values. A possible explanation for these patterns is that entropy’s impact on pricing is most pronounced during these periods, offering investors who favor entropy a better chance to justify their choice of stocks with higher growth potential.
Considering the impact of IE on pricing, we explore whether entropy can shed light on the IV puzzle, where stocks with higher IV tend to have lower expected returns. This inverse relationship between IV and future returns, documented by Ang et al. (2006) in the U.S. and Ang et al. (2009) internationally, is intriguing as it contradicts current theories [1]. On one hand, theories suggest that IV should not influence pricing if an investor diversifies their portfolio completely. On the other hand, if an investor doesn’t diversify fully, IV should theoretically lead to higher expected returns, as per Boyer et al. (2010). Yet, our discovery that IV is a key indicator of IE suggests a new perspective: investors might be drawn to high-IV stocks not for their volatility, but rather for their ‘lottery-like’ return characteristics, which may lead them to accept lower average returns. Our results show that different proxies for lottery-like payoffs generate similar results, providing further support for the explanation we offer.
To understand how entropy preference influences the IV puzzle, we conducted tests using our model that anticipates entropy. We look at how expected returns and IV are related when we factor in our predictions of entropy. Using a technique similar to the one used by Ang et al. (2009), we create portfolio groups that vary widely in IV but not in predicted IE. After adjusting for predicted IE, we see a weaker connection between IV and stock returns. In particular, the difference in average returns between portfolios with high IV and those with low IV becomes smaller and not statistically significant. Additionally, the difference in the Carhart alphas for these portfolios decreases from −2.47% to −2.14% monthly. Considering entropy preferences is crucial for understanding why stocks with high IV often have lower average returns. We also try to separate the impacts of predicted entropy and IV. The negative relationship between predicted IE and average returns seems to be more solidly backed by both empirical data and theoretical reasoning.
The structure of this paper is outlined as follows: Section 2 delves into the reasoning behind our empirical analyses, emphasizing the theoretical connections between a preference for entropy and the expected returns of investments. In Section 3, we introduce a model for predicting entropy and discuss the results of its estimations. Section 4 presents data. Section 5 analyses the cross-sectional distribution of firm-level risk factors. Section 6 explores the effects of IE on stock pricing. Section 7 differentiates between the impacts of IE and IV, and investigates whether a preference for entropy can explain why there is often a negative relationship between IV and expected returns. The paper concludes with Section 8.
2. Motivation
Entropy has long been a key concept in information theory, as shown in works by Holm (1993) and Maasoumi (1993). Drawing from this foundation, our empirical study is inspired by various asset pricing research. The speculative tendencies of investors have spurred the creation of several theoretical models to understand the impact of these behaviors on asset prices. For instance, Usta and Kantar (2011), along with Caplin, Dean, and Leahy (2022), have proposed models that show a mix of investor preferences regarding entropy. In their models, some investors are drawn to entropy, while traditional investors focus on mean-variance optimization to maximize their portfolio returns. These investors assign a high value to stocks that exhibit positive entropy and often maintain portfolios that are not fully diversified, to enhance their exposure to positive entropy. In the market, prices reflect this, resulting in stocks with high entropy typically showing negative returns compared to the overall market portfolio. In a balanced market, where portfolio weights are carefully considered, the additional cost of acquiring more shares equals the benefit gained from them. As a result, in such a market equilibrium, investors often choose portfolios that are less diversified, leading to the pricing of total entropy and IE as described by Gulko (1999, 2002). Maasoumi and Racine (2002) have found that their model predicting expected entropy can effectively explain investor behaviors in stock markets.
An additional aspect of our research is the comparison between IE and other unique moments (characteristics) of stocks. This approach is inspired by Shannon’s work in 1948, where he compared entropy with variance (a measure of volatility). Earlier studies like those by Maasoumi and Theil (1979) investigated entropy-based measures related to income differences, while Mukherjee and Ratnaparkhi (1986) and Cressie (1993) explored the link between entropy and volatility. Jiang, Wu, and Zhou (2018) introduced an entropy-focused method for assessing asymmetric movements in markets, finding that greater asymmetric comovement tends to predict higher stock returns. Chernov, Graveline, and Zviadadze (2018) employed entropy as a broad measure of variance in exchange rates to gauge currency risk. Entropy is particularly useful as it captures both regular and extreme risks in a single value, equating to variance under normal distribution but extending to include more complex risks otherwise. However, there has been limited research on how entropy relates to, or differs from, other statistical moments in stock analysis. Our study aims to illuminate this area by assessing whether IE and other unique stock characteristics are reflected in stock prices. We build upon the work of Ebrahimi, Maasoumi, and Soofi (1999) and Maasoumi and Racine (2002), focusing on comparing IE with other well-known idiosyncratic moments in stock returns.
In a different approach, Buchen and Michael created a model based on investors’ prospect theory, showing that even though investors have varied holdings, the market balance they reach leads them to maintain portfolios that are not very diversified. The theory of cumulative prospect utility suggests that investors tend to give more importance to extreme probabilities. According to Gulko (1999, 2002), in situations where assets have confined return patterns, market balances formed under prospect theory can determine the price of entropy in those asset returns. Philippatos and Wilson (1972) discovered that having ideal expectations can lower the average returns of such confined assets in market balance. These theoretical findings, which connect entropy with expected returns, serve as the foundation for our empirical research.
Lastly, our study is inspired by the role of entropy in analyzing the predictability of financial markets over time. Researchers like Darbellay and Wuertz (2000) have explored the effectiveness of entropy in studying financial time series. Dimpfl and Peter (2018) demonstrated that investors could use group transfer entropy for predicting market volatility. Moreover, entropy has been used to measure market efficiency in various sectors, including foreign exchange (Oh, Kim, & Eom, 2007), stocks (Risso, 2008, 2009), and commodities (Martina, Rodriguez, Escarela-Perez, & Alvarez-Ramirez, 2011; Ortiz-Cruz, Rodriguez, Ibarra-Valdez, & Alvarez-Ramirez, 2012; Kristoufek & Vosvrda, 2014), focusing on how well an entire data series can be predicted using total entropy. However, entropy’s ability to forecast events with small probabilities presents challenges. Current methods in asset pricing often rely on lagged predictors like IV, IS, and IK as risk indicators, assuming that these factors remain stable over time. Yet, this stability is questionable for IE. For instance, Maasoumi and Racine (2002) developed a model to forecast entropy and noticed that it somewhat reveals nonlinear relationships within stock return series. This issue encourages us to develop a new approach for estimating the expected entropy.
3. An entropy prediction model
We present a model predicting entropy, which incorporates historical returns, established idiosyncratic risk factors, and typical company traits. Our first step involves applying the well-known Fama and French (1993) three-factor model to daily total stock returns data for each company:
We utilize the residual returns calculated from equation (1) to create a measure of IE, based on fundamental concepts from information theory. Entropy quantifies the likelihood spread within a probability distribution. The commonly adopted method for this is Shannon entropy. However, extensions to Shannon’s original theory have introduced different entropy metrics, such as the widely-used Renyi entropy proposed in 1961. According to Renyi’s approach, consider stock
An
The logarithm used in equation (3) is designed to calculate the information produced by a particular event of a variable, expressed as the logarithm of its occurrence probability. Considering a continuous probability distribution with a density function
Let’s assume
While we rely on equation (5) for calculating individual stock’s IE, the method for computing IE for a portfolio differs and is crucial to understand conceptually. Consider an investment in two stocks, labeled 1 and 2, with their respective residual returns
When dealing with two independent stock returns, the IE of the portfolio is simply the combined total of each stock’s individual IE, expressed as
Based on the theoretical background provided, we apply Shannon entropy as outlined in Equation (5), along with the principles of entropy construction for portfolios, in carrying out our empirical analysis.
To draw comparisons between IE and established idiosyncratic risk metrics, we also calculate
IE, as defined by Benedetto et al. (2016), evaluates the irregularities or disorders in residual returns. This metric assesses the unpredictability of residual returns, with a high IE indicating a high degree of randomness and uncertainty. In essence, returns with high IE are characterized by a lack of discernible patterns, rendering them almost completely random. On the other hand, low IE suggests a more deterministic nature of returns, where patterns and predictability are more evident (Kristoufek & Vosvrda, 2014). This concept of entropy differs significantly from IV and IS. IV, specifically, measures the dispersion or spread of residual returns around their mean, focusing solely on the extent to which these returns deviate from the average. In contrast, IS delves into the directional bias and extent of distribution in the residual returns. It quantifies the asymmetry in the distribution, indicating whether the returns are more likely to lean towards one direction over the other.
While IS captures the asymmetry in the distribution of residual returns, it is distinct from IE and IV in its focus on the direction and extent of this asymmetry. IS reflects the relative length of the tails in the PDF, providing insights into how much the distribution of returns skews away from the norm. For instance, a positive IS value indicates that the distribution of returns has a longer right tail, suggesting a greater likelihood of higher-than-average returns. Conversely, a negative IS value implies the opposite, with a longer left tail indicating a greater likelihood of lower-than-average returns. IK, on the other hand, is a measure that indicates the peak value of the PDF curve at the average value. It specifically addresses the thickness of the tails and the steepness of the distribution curve, offering insights into the likelihood of extreme returns. Unlike IE and IV, which focus on randomness and variance, respectively, IK provides a unique perspective on the extreme values in the distribution, highlighting the potential for outlier events in the return series.
4. Data
Our dataset includes stocks listed on DataStream from January 1988 to June 2019. We use daily stock returns to compute monthly risk factors. Following Ang et al. (2009) in terms of the starting point for data collection and analysis, we have compiled information on all active stocks across 23 developed countries, spanning from 1 January 1988 to 30 June 2019. The dataset encompasses 3,100 stocks, excluding those priced under 5 dollars and the bottom 5% in terms of market value. The broad duration of this dataset ensures a comprehensive analysis that encompasses various economic cycles, financial crises, and diverse risk conditions.
5. Analyzing cross-sectional distribution of firm-level risk factors
Figure 1 displays the cross-sectional distribution of
In our asset pricing evaluations, we need to determine the anticipated IE (
This approach enables us to observe how the relationship between firm-specific risk factors and IE varies over time, resulting in practical monthly estimates of expected IE.
We adopt this method to determine the expected IE over a 60-day formation period, though the selection of this period is somewhat subjective. This is based on the understanding that investors often focus on a stock’s short-term growth prospects rather than long-term high returns. A 60-day formation period suggests that investors use data from the previous 60 days to make their estimates for Equations (11) and (12) [6].
The firm-specific risk factors
Table 1 presents the summary statistics for the risk factors used in our cross-sectional regression analyses. In Panel A, IE shows a relatively low mean value (0.14) compared to IS (0.22) and IK (2.01). This lower value of IE may indicate its effectiveness as a predictor, given that our aim is to forecast stock returns using this measure. Benedetto et al. (2016) observed that high entropy, indicative of significant irregularity, leads to the unpredictability of financial time series. Essentially, higher entropy suggests greater unpredictability, whereas lower entropy indicates fewer irregularities (disorders), enhancing the series’ predictability. Martina et al. (2011) also found that higher entropy values are associated with more varied and less predictable market developments. Panels A and B also detail the descriptive statistics and correlations of these factors, respectively. IE shows the most positive correlation with IV (22%), MAX (17%), MIN (8%), co-skewness (11%), and HML (1%), though these correlations are relatively small. The strongest correlation observed is between IE and IV. It’s noteworthy that other conventional risk factors in our sample exhibit either low positive or negative correlations, suggesting that IE is largely uncorrelated with these standard factors.
We recognize that Equation (11) is an economical model for predicting IE, and as such, it does not include some potential risk factors identified in previous studies. For example, Amaya et al. (2015) incorporate certain risk factors related to realized skewness. When we add these factors to our regression analyses, we observe an increase in explanatory power. However, including them results in the exclusion of many data points from our observations. We also tested our models with a leverage factor and found that, despite the lack of this data for many firms in DataStream, it modestly enhances the adjusted R2. Given these limitations, we choose to proceed with our sample using a more concise set of risk factors in our cross-sectional asset-pricing estimates, ensuring we maintain a broader range of firms in the analysis [7].
Panel A of Table 2 displays the outcomes of our monthly calculations based on Equation (11) for the primary sample set. Each row presents results from different regression models, ranging from model 1 to model 6. To summarize these regressions, we provide the average value of the coefficients and the percentage of months in which the estimated coefficients are significant at the 5% level and have the same sign as the average coefficients. However, as there’s no adjustment for potential cross-sectional correlations in residuals, this significance should be considered only as a general indicator for comparison.
The table uses a 60-day period to define
In Panel A, Model 6 incorporates all risk factors, with only
Panel B of Table 2 offers robustness checks for the predictive regression analyses presented in Panel A. In Model 7, a shorter 30-day period is used to calculate
In Panel B, Models 8, 9, and 10 replicate the regressions from Model 6. However, they calculate the metrics
Overall, the findings in this section indicate that a straightforward cross-sectional model, incorporating lagged IE, IS, IV, IK, market excess return, firm size, book-to-market ratio, momentum, co-skewness, liquidity, MAX, and MIN is effective in helping investors predict IE. The following section will delve into whether IE, as forecasted by this model, can elucidate the cross-section of expected returns.
6. Expected entropy and average returns
Our primary goal with the entropy prediction model is to determine if expected entropy can enhance our comprehension of the variations in stock returns. To achieve this, we conduct a series of conventional asset-pricing tests, assessing the relationship between expected entropy and average returns. This analysis is guided by the theoretical frameworks outlined in sections 1 and 2. Initially, we investigate how average returns vary among stocks with differing levels of expected entropy. Subsequently, we explore how predicted entropy impacts the variations in stock returns using the Fama and MacBeth (1973) approach.
6.1 Portfolios constructed by predicted entropy
Firstly, we calculate the expected entropy measures,
Table 3 showcases descriptive statistics for the five portfolios arranged according to each idiosyncratic risk factor. Here, Portfolio 1 contains stocks with the lowest predicted risk, while Portfolio 5 contains stocks with the highest. The first column in each panel reveals the time-series average of the value-weighted portfolio returns. Notably, the average returns of the portfolios sorted by IE exhibit a consistent downward trend from Portfolios 1 to 5. The returns are significantly lower in Portfolio 5 (−1.33%) compared to Portfolio 1 (1.09%), resulting in a monthly spread of −2.42% with a t-statistic of −4.49. This indicates significant differences in average returns across stocks with varying levels of predicted entropy. The most substantial drop in mean returns occurs between the third and fourth portfolios.
Panels B and C indicate that portfolios organized according to IS and IV also display a consistently decreasing trend from Portfolio 1 to 5, mirroring the pattern seen in the IE-sorted portfolios. These findings align with the research of Ang et al. (2006) and Boyer et al. (2010), who observed similar trends for IV and IS. Conversely, Panel D reveals that portfolios sorted by IK show an increasing trend across the portfolios, corroborating the findings of Conrad et al. (2013). Given that existing research doesn’t establish a clear expected relationship between total entropy (or IE) and subsequent returns, the congruence of our IV, IS, and IK results with prior studies lends credibility to our findings regarding IE.
While predicted entropy seems to be a crucial factor in determining returns, using lagged entropy alone isn’t adequate for accurate return prediction. To further investigate this, we conduct the same analysis as in Table 3 but categorize stocks into portfolios based on predicted entropy using
There are two key observations in this section. Firstly, the downward trends in the portfolios categorized by IE, IS, and IV, along with the upward trend in those sorted by IK, align with the findings in Table 2. In that table, IS and IV show positive relationships with IE, while IK displays a negative correlation. Secondly, and more importantly, the final column in each panel reveals that the return spreads for portfolios based on expected idiosyncratic risk are more substantial, even after risk adjustment. We also present the Carhart model alphas for each portfolio. The spread in alphas for IE (Panel A) is notably significant, with Portfolio 1 achieving a monthly alpha of 1.19% and Portfolio 5 achieving a monthly alpha of −1.28%, leading to a statistically significant spread of −2.47% per month. In essence, Table 3 illustrates that predicted entropy has a negative association with expected returns, even after accounting for standard risk factors.
6.2 FM regressions
In this subsection, we delve deeper into the pricing effects of IE by employing cross-sectional regression analyses based on the Fama and MacBeth (1973) (FM) methodology. Our analysis reveals a consistent, significant statistical and economic relationship between predicted entropy and average returns across different stocks, a trend that remains even when we account for standard risk factors.
To determine the expected entropy measures
In our analysis,
Table 4 presents the average over time of the
Although there is no established risk price for entropy in existing literature for comparison, we focus on other risk factors. Consistent with expectations, the coefficients for IS and IV are negative and significant, while those for IK are positive and significant. Likewise, HML, co-skewness, and liquidity exhibit negative and significant loadings, whereas MOM shows insignificant negative loadings. In conclusion, Table 4 indicates that expected IE contributes to explaining the cross-sectional variation in expected returns, extending beyond the influence of traditional standard risk factors.
We also assess the effectiveness of the IE-based models in comparison to other models by looking at the R-squared values and the pricing errors. In columns 2 to 4 of Table 4, it is observed that the model using the IE portfolio exhibits higher R-squared values and lower pricing errors compared to the IV model, while it shows lower R-squared values and higher pricing errors when compared to the IS and IK models. Consequently, IE demonstrates better performance than IV in terms of achieving higher R-squared and lower pricing errors.
6.3 Robustness checks
To verify the consistency of the results presented in Table 4, we performed two robustness tests, the outcomes of which are detailed in Table 5. These tests involve altering the risk formation period and the number of portfolios to assess the stability of our findings related to entropy pricing. Through these checks, we consistently observe that the coefficients of predicted entropy maintain their negative and significant nature.
6.3.1 Alternative formation periods and portfolios
Table 4 previously presented the Fama-MacBeth (FM) regression results using a 60-day formation period, calculating the expected entropy measures
Table 4 initially presented FM regression results based on monthly sorting of stocks into 100 portfolios by expected entropy. We now adjust the number of portfolios to both a smaller (50 portfolios) and a larger (200 portfolios) scale and rerun the cross-sectional tests on these newly sorted portfolios. Panel B of Table 5 replicates the analysis from Table 4 but uses 50 and 200 portfolios as test assets. The findings indicate that the FM regression executed with 200 portfolios displays greater statistical significance than that executed with 50 portfolios, as evidenced by higher t-statistics and adjusted R-squared values. This significance surpasses the baseline results shown in the last column of Table 4. Nonetheless, the IE coefficients consistently remain negative and significant. The IV coefficient, however, shows insignificance (significance) in the 50-portfolio (100-portfolio) sample.
Additionally, we conduct two further checks in this section [9]. Firstly, we explore the impact of the risk formation period by calculating
Lastly, we shift our focus to total entropy measures rather than IE measures for entropy forecasting and pricing tests. This adjustment is important to gauge our findings’ reliance on the Fama and French three-factor model (Equation (1)) used for deriving IE measures. Our theoretical model suggests that investors are concerned with not just IE but the total entropy of their portfolio. When we conduct regressions using total entropy measures, there is a slight alteration in our pricing results, but the coefficient on
6.3.2 Alternative entropy factors
In Equation (5), the calculation of Shannon entropy is based on the assumption that α equals one, which is a common practice in constructing entropy measures. However, modifying α and incorporating additional assumptions into Shannon entropy necessitates verifying whether our findings remain valid under these changes. To confirm that our Shannon entropy isn’t influenced by the monthly total return, we redo our empirical analyses using three alternative entropy measures. The first of these is the Renyi (1961) collision entropy measure, where α is set to two [10].
The second entropy measure we use is the Tsallis (1988) entropy, where for any positive real number α, the entropy of order α for a probability
This measure is similar to Shannon entropy, but it differs in that the degree of homogeneity under the convex linearity condition is set to α rather than 1.
Lastly, we apply the Kullback and Leibler (1951) cross-entropy measure, which is based on two key assumptions: (1) each probability
We create three alternative entropy factors by employing Equations (14), (15), and (16), and then conduct our empirical analyses again for each of these measures. In every instance, the outcomes closely align with those of Model 7 in Table 4. Across all regression models, we observed a consistently significant negative price for entropy risk. While Panel C indicates somewhat lower statistical significance compared to the other panels, the negative and significant nature of entropy risk is still evident.
6.3.3 Time-series effects
Figure 1 illustrates the temporal characteristics of predicted entropy. We now turn our attention to addressing whether our cross-sectional pricing results exhibit any significant temporal variations. For each month t, Figure 2 presents a rolling average of the predicted entropy premium (
The series demonstrates a negative correlation with the graph of the predicted entropy premium. This suggests that the entropy premium tends to be more pronounced during speculative periods when expected entropy can be forecasted with higher accuracy and ease. To examine these relationships further, we proceed to conduct an analysis using Equation (17):
Table 6 corroborates the suggestion from Panel A of Figure 1: the predicted entropy premium is most negative in times of high dispersion, high average, high skewness in predicted entropy, and when entropy is predictable. Conversely, this premium is most positive when the kurtosis of predicted entropy is high. The statistical significance of these five explanatory variables is notable. While these findings are preliminary and require further investigation to precisely define the temporal variations in entropy pricing, the evidence in Table 6 strongly supports the likelihood of such variations.
7. Entropy, skewness, volatility, and expected returns
Numerous studies in existing literature have focused on the relationship between IV and IS measures and expected returns, compared to the relatively less explored link between entropy and expected returns. Given our previous findings of a connection between IE and returns, this section aims to determine whether the relationship between IE and returns is directly tied to entropy itself or if it is influenced, at least in part, by IV and IS. To do this, we start by conducting the FM regressions as previously described and investigate how entropy might be associated with the established relationships between expected returns and the measures of IV and IS.
7.1 Regressions on individual stocks
The FM regressions described in subsection (6.2) calculate the price of IE by grouping stocks into quantile portfolios based on their expected entropy. However, this method might unintentionally exaggerate the impact of expected entropy and other risk factors, such as IS, IV, and IK. To mitigate this potential overestimation, an alternative approach is to apply the FM regressions at the individual stock level. While FM regressions are more commonly performed at the portfolio level in academic research, we opt to conduct our analyses at the individual stock level to assess if this approach influences our results. Consequently, we execute the following cross-sectional FM regression for each month:
Table 7 details the results of Equation (18). In Model 1, where only expected entropy is included in the regression, a significant negative coefficient is found at the 1% confidence level. Model 2, which includes only IS in the regression, reveals a larger coefficient for IS both in terms of economic significance (size) and statistical significance (t-statistic). Conversely, Model 3, which includes only IV, shows a negative coefficient for IV, but it has lower economic and statistical significance compared to the other two risk factors. Model 5 incorporates all three factors and echoes the findings of Models 1 to 3: the coefficient for expected IE is more significant both economically and statistically compared to IV, but less so than IS. Models 6 and 7 include expected entropy along with other risk factor loadings, and in both models, the coefficients for expected entropy remain negative and significant at the 1% level, with the economic and statistical significance of the IS (IV) coefficient being higher (lower) than that of IE.
Overall, while the risk coefficients in most models of Table 7 are smaller compared to our baseline portfolio results, the expected IE demonstrates considerable explanatory power in the individual stock analyses. When other risk factors are not included, expected entropy has a more explanatory power than IV. However, IV’s explanatory power increases after adjusting for other risk factors. Given that expected entropy is a combination of other risk factors used as control variables, its explanatory power understandably diminishes when all risk factors are included in the regression. Table 7 also indicates that the explanatory power of expected entropy surpasses that of IV. These FM regression results confirm that our previous findings, which involved sorting stocks based on expected entropy, are not disproportionately influenced by this sorting method.
In Table 7, Models 1 to 4 show that when individual stocks are used as test assets, the IE-based model yields higher R-squared values and lower pricing errors compared to the IV and IK models, while it has lower R-squared values and higher pricing errors when compared to the IS models. This indicates that the IE model surpasses both IV and IK in terms of achieving higher R-squared and lower pricing errors.
7.2 Regressions with IS- and IV-sorted portfolios
This subsection examines whether categorizing stocks into portfolios based on expected entropy skews our results towards favoring IE over IS and IV. Initially, we group stocks into quantile portfolios based on IS as compared to expected IE and perform similar groupings for IV relative to expected IE. Subsequently, we utilize the Fama-MacBeth (FM) regressions to assess the risk factors’ prices. If the sorting method biases our results towards the factor used for creating the quantile portfolios, then these FM regressions could offer a more accurate estimation of the impact of the expected IE factor.
In conducting the FM regressions, as specified in Equation (11), we differ only in that we sort stocks into 100 portfolios each month based on IV, rather than expected entropy. The outcomes of these regressions are detailed in Panels A and B of Table 8. When sorting by IV (Panel A), it’s observed that the IE coefficients exhibit greater economic and statistical significance – evidenced by larger sizes, higher t-statistics, and increased adjusted R-squared values – compared to both IV and IS. Sorting by IS yields results similar to those in Table 4: the IE coefficients are negative and significant at the 1% level, and their economic and statistical significance are higher (lower) than IV (IS), as indicated by their sizes, t-statistics, and adjusted R-squared values.
In summary, Table 8 demonstrates that the notable explanatory power of expected IE is not influenced by the sorting methodology used, and that expected entropy retains its distinct explanatory power compared to IV and IS, even when these latter factors are used as the basis for portfolio formation.
7.3 Entropy and the IV puzzle
While earlier sections highlighted the pricing impacts of IE, we now aim to explore IE’s role in explaining the negative relationship between IV and expected returns, as identified by Ang et al. (2006). Additionally, we seek to differentiate the influences of IE and IV on expected returns. This investigation is crucial for two key reasons. Firstly, a negative correlation between return and risk challenges conventional beliefs about investors' utility. Secondly, it brings attention to potential market inefficiencies, such as limited information disclosure or restrictions on short-selling, as noted by Boehme, Danielsen, Kumar, and Sorescu (2009) and Jiang, Xu, and Yao (2009). However, the IV puzzle, when viewed through the lens of entropy preference, is unlikely to stem from market imperfections. If investors favor stocks with positive entropy, they might be willing to accept lower returns on high IV stocks if those stocks promise high returns. This rationale aligns with the approach described in section 3 for calculating entropy, where entropy is inherently non-negative.
To delve into how predicted entropy affects the IV puzzle, we start by revisiting the principal findings of Ang et al. (2006) and then assess how these findings are altered when factoring in predicted entropy. Subsequently, we differentiate the effects of IE and IV and conduct a reverse analysis to determine the extent to which IV can account for our observations regarding the relationship between expected IE and returns.
7.3.1 IV and expected returns
In this section, we adopt Ang et al.'s (2006) methodology and start by categorizing stocks into quintile portfolios each month based on their
Table 9 also includes two entropy risk factors. The first, shown in column 4, is the total entropy time-series estimate for each portfolio’s returns, displaying a trend where higher IV portfolios exhibit higher total entropy returns. The second factor, the firm entropy presented in column 6, represents the time-averaged value-weighted cross-sectional average of
7.3.2 Conditional sorting
In this section, we explore the contribution of IE in clarifying the IV anomaly. Following the methodology used by Ang et al. (2006, 2009), we perform a double-sorting technique that incorporates expected entropy. At the end of each month, we first sort stocks into five quintiles based on their
Panel A of Table 11 suggests that entropy preference plays a key role in the returns of IV portfolios. Column 1 shows that the range of average returns across portfolios sorted by conditional IV is significantly smaller than those sorted by unconditional IV. The highest-to-lowest IV portfolio yields a monthly return premium of −2.09% with a t-statistic of −3.08, which is lower than the premium reported in Table 9. This indicates that the IV puzzle identified by Ang et al. (2006) is considerably reduced when we account for expected IE.
Columns 2 to 4 of Panel A in Table 11 detail the standard deviation, skewness, and total entropy of returns for the portfolios ranked by IV, taking expected IE into account. Columns 5 to 9 provide value-weighted cross-sectional averages of IV, IE, and size, as well as the CAPM and Fama-French (FF) model alphas for each portfolio. Our findings indicate minimal variation in entropy across the five IV portfolios, suggesting that our expected entropy model accurately predicts entropy. The average firm entropy also shows smaller variations compared to the unconditional IV-sorted portfolios in Table 9, especially with slightly lower firm entropy in high IV portfolios.
Columns 8 and 9 of Panel A report risk-adjusted pricing spreads across the portfolios using CAPM and FF model alphas. The highest IV portfolio exhibits a significant CAPM alpha of −2.47%, albeit less than the unconditional high IV portfolio from Table 9, indicating the persistence of the IV puzzle based on CAPM risk-adjusted alpha. For the FF model, the high IV portfolio’s alpha is −2.14%, which is also smaller than the unconditional high IV portfolio’s FF alpha reported in Table 9. Thus, controlling for IE results in much smaller spreads in the CAPM and FF alphas.
The bottom row of Panel A uses an Unconditional Minus Conditional (UMC) portfolio to assess improvements in entropy forecasting. This UMC portfolio strategy involves taking long positions in the unconditional high/low IV portfolio and short positions in the conditional high/low IV portfolio. The results strongly support the explanatory power of the predicted entropy, with the CAPM alpha on the UMC portfolio being −0.20% (t-statistic of −2.15) and the FF alpha being −0.23% (t-statistic of −2.26).
Panel B of Table 11 follows a similar analysis as Panel A, but reverses the roles of expected entropy and IV. This approach aims to determine if IV contributes to explaining the returns of portfolios ranked by expected entropy, as shown in Table 3. The findings reveal that including IV reduces the return spread of the highest-to-lowest entropy portfolio compared to Table 9. The FF alpha spread between these portfolios is −2.25% per month, even after controlling for IV. The UMC portfolio in Panel B, constructed with reversed roles for expected entropy and IV, shows significant alphas at the 5% level. This indicates that expected IE more effectively explains the negative relationship between IV and returns than IV does in explaining the negative association between expected entropy and returns.
7.3.3 IE and lottery-like features
This paper uses two scenarios for analyzing the lottery-like feature of entropy that helps explain the IV puzzle. To conduct the analyses, we used the analyses of Bali et al. (2011). The first analysis is based on Panel A in Table 3, where Portfolio 1 (low IE) is the portfolio of stocks with the lowest IE during the past 60-day formation period, and portfolio 5 (high IE) is the portfolio of stocks with the highest IE during the past 60-day formation period. The raw return difference between decile 5 (high IE) and decile 1 (low IE) is −2.42% per month with a t-statistic of −4.49. In addition to the raw returns, Table 3 also presents the intercepts (Carhart four-factor alphas). As shown in the last row of Table 3, the difference in alphas between the high IE and low IE portfolios is −2.47% per month with a t-statistic of −4.46. This difference is economically significant and statistically significant at all conventional levels. Taking a closer look at the average returns and alphas across deciles, it is clear that the pattern is not one of a uniform declines as IE increases. The average returns of deciles 1–3 are approximately the same, in the range of 0.69–1.09% per month; but, going from decile 4 to decile 5, average returns drop significantly, from 0.69 to −1.08% and then to −1.33% per month. The alphas for the first three deciles are also almost similar, but again they fall dramatically for deciles 4 through 5. Given a preference for upside potential, investors may be willing to pay more for, and accept lower expected returns on, assets with these extremely high positive returns. In other words, it is conceivable that investors view these stocks as valuable lottery-like assets, with a small chance of a large gain.
The second alternative analysis of the extent to which a stock exhibits lottery-like payoffs is to compute IE over longer past periods. We construct the estimates
These analyses show that different proxies for lottery-like payoffs generate similar results, confirming their robustness and thus providing further support for the explanation we offer.
7.3.4 Discussion
The concept of “entropy,” originating from classical mechanics and information theory, is a measure of disorder or randomness within a system. For example, a stock market with predictable behavior and no irregularities would have a low IE, indicating a structured environment. On the other hand, a market with erratic stock prices demonstrates high IE, reflecting its unpredictability. Unlike general finance risk factors like volatility or market beta, which track overall asset movements, IE specifically zeroes in on the surprise element or unpredictability in stock movements. For instance, two stocks with similar volatility levels may differ in IE if one shows more erratic behavior. This is evident in real-world situations, such as a company’s stock price movement around earnings announcements or during mergers, or its debt repayment predictability, all of which can indicate varying levels of IE.
Table 11’s findings highlight IE’s significant role in understanding the lower average returns of stocks with high IV. The results also show that IV helps to explain the observed negative correlation between expected IE and returns. A notable point is that a risk factor can retain its explanatory power even when another factor is considered. Both factors – entropy and volatility – have overlapping estimates in their explanatory powers, making it challenging to attribute these to one specific factor. Since there’s no established framework linking IE to expected returns, this paper contributes significantly to this area.
In exploring the IV puzzle, the entropy-based explanation adds to other theories addressing market imperfections, like short-selling constraints or varied investor opinions. Entropy preference is a key element in understanding why investors value stocks with high idiosyncratic risk. High valuations from entropy-preferring, under-diversified investors are more likely to be stable in high short-selling cost scenarios. Additionally, diverse investor opinions might indicate a wider range of entropy preferences, where under-diversified investors value potential stock gains higher than their well-diversified counterparts.
8. Conclusion
The risk management field has extensively studied IV and IS, but the empirical analysis exploring the connection between IE and stock returns has been largely overlooked. Our research aims to bridge this gap by implementing a model that uses predicted entropy to elucidate the cross-section of stock returns. Our findings reveal that lagged IV is a stronger predictor of entropy compared to lagged IE. Therefore, we incorporate IV and other risk factors as controls to predict IE. This approach to predicting entropy demonstrates significant pricing impacts, particularly in line with the Carhart four-factor model. When sorting stocks based on predicted entropy, we observe that the Carhart alpha for portfolios with lower entropy surpasses that of higher entropy portfolios by −2.47% per month. We identified a negative correlation between IE and expected returns, indicating that investors can potentially earn a premium from stocks with higher entropy levels. Delving deeper, our analysis suggests that this premium may be attributable to the fact that high IV is a reliable indicator of stocks likely to exhibit high future entropy exposure. Consequently, our results point to forecasted entropy as a key factor explaining the negative relationship between IV and expected returns. Although market imperfections might also influence this relationship, our findings hint that understanding investors’ preferences could be a crucial starting point in unraveling this complex dynamic.
The discovery of a negative relationship between expected IE and stock returns carries profound implications for portfolio management and risk assessment strategies. Investors and financial analysts could leverage the insights derived from this study to refine their models for predicting stock performance. By incorporating measures of IE into these models, they can potentially achieve a more nuanced understanding of the risk-return trade-off associated with individual stocks. This approach could guide more informed decisions regarding asset allocation, particularly in the context of diversification strategies aimed at mitigating unsystematic risk. Furthermore, financial institutions might consider developing new financial products or investment tools that explicitly account for idiosyncratic entropy, thus offering investors more sophisticated means to manage their portfolios in alignment with their risk preferences.
The notable connection between exposure to IE and expected returns presents a compelling topic for future empirical and theoretical research. Such studies should aim to thoroughly explore the underlying factors driving this risk and how they relate to stock risk premiums. Consequently, developing co-entropy risk measures and investigating their correlations with stock risk premiums would be a valuable direction for upcoming research endeavors.
Figures
Descriptive statistics of IE prediction variables
IE | IS | IK | IV | MKT | SMB | HML | MOM | Co-skew | Liquidity | MAX | MIN | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A: baseline results | ||||||||||||
Mean | 0.14 | 0.22 | 2.01 | 0.024 | 0.02 | 0.018 | 0.088 | 0.03 | 0.40 | −0.09 | 1.28 | −1.04 |
Median | 0.13 | 0.22 | 1.99 | 0.023 | 0.05 | 0.011 | 0.082 | 0.06 | 0.40 | −0.10 | 0.37 | −0.39 |
Std. Dev | 0.05 | 0.11 | 0.30 | 0.005 | 0.09 | 0.05 | 0.07 | 0.08 | 0.11 | 0.05 | 12.22 | 9.27 |
Skewness | 1.06 | −0.28 | 0.86 | 1.99 | −0.21 | 8.57 | −6.24 | −1.03 | 0.27 | −0.63 | 4.44 | 0.55 |
Kurtosis | 8.83 | 4.02 | 5.38 | 9.94 | 11.47 | 205.08 | 111.4 | 16.91 | 2.16 | 36.38 | 8.26 | 1.34 |
Sharp ratio | 2.80 | 2.00 | 6.70 | 4.80 | 0.22 | 0.36 | 1.25 | 0.37 | 3.63 | −1.80 | 1.29 | 1.08 |
Panel B: correlations | ||||||||||||
IE | 1.00 | |||||||||||
IS | −0.05 | 1.00 | ||||||||||
IK | −0.21 | 0.05 | 1.00 | |||||||||
IV | 0.22 | −0.03 | −0.22 | 1.00 | ||||||||
MKT | 0.00 | 0.04 | 0.00 | 0.01 | 1.00 | |||||||
SMB | −0.01 | 0.02 | 0.01 | 0.00 | −0.14 | 1.00 | ||||||
HML | 0.01 | −0.02 | 0.01 | 0.00 | 0.07 | 0.00 | 1.00 | |||||
MOM | −0.03 | −0.02 | 0.00 | −0.05 | −0.22 | 0.05 | −0.02 | 1.00 | ||||
Co-skew | 0.11 | 0.03 | −0.32 | 0.27 | −0.01 | −0.01 | −0.02 | 0.02 | 1.00 | |||
Liquidity | −0.26 | −0.06 | 0.26 | −0.11 | 0.00 | 0.01 | 0.02 | −0.01 | −0.64 | 1.00 | ||
MAX | 0.17 | −0.12 | −0.26 | 0.26 | 0.11 | −0.09 | −0.15 | 0.05 | −0.10 | −0.15 | 1.00 | |
MIN | 0.08 | −0.16 | −0.29 | 0.28 | 0.09 | −0.12 | −0.09 | 0.01 | −0.08 | −0.12 | −0.22 | 1.00 |
Note(s): Panel A provides descriptive statistics for the risk factors used to predict firm entropy through monthly cross-sectional regression analyses. IE, IV, IS, and IK are calculated using Equations (5), (8), (9), and (10), respectively, based on residuals determined by Equation (1). MKT represents the market’s excess return; SMB denotes the excess return of small-cap stocks over large-cap stocks; HML is the excess return of high book-to-market stocks over low book-to-market stocks; MOM calculates the difference in returns between two portfolios with high previous returns and two with low previous returns. Co-skewness and liquidity are derived as per Harvey and Siddique (2000) and Pastor and Stambaugh (2003), respectively. MAX refers to the highest daily return within a month, and MIN is the inverse of the lowest daily return in the same period. Panel B additionally presents correlations among these risk factors. The dataset covers 3,100 firms from January 1988 to June 2019
Source(s): Created by the author
The IE prediction regressions
Model | Adj.R2 | |||||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A: descriptive statistics | ||||||||||||||
1 | 0.039 (0.95) | 0.62 (1.00) | 7.01% | |||||||||||
2 | 0.062 (0.79) | 0.17 (0.79) | 1.55% | |||||||||||
3 | 0.035 (0.90) | 6.88 (0.942) | 38.15% | |||||||||||
4 | 0.10 (0.93) | −0.038 (0.792) | 3.99% | |||||||||||
5 | 0.030 (0.89) | 0.31 (0.891) | 0.14 (0.696) | 3.89 (0.865) | −0.007 (0.244) | 44.29% | ||||||||
6 | 0.025 (0.71) | 0.21 (0.712) | 0.20 (0.511) | 3.88 (0.782) | 0.0011 (0.397) | −0.072 (0.622) | −0.016 (0.555) | 0.012 (0.788) | −0.042 (0.572) | 0.055 (0.533) | 0.66 (0.733) | −0.059 (0.522) | 0.012 (0.332) | 50.11% |
Panel B: robustness on different formation periods | ||||||||||||||
7 (30 days) | 0.033 (0.94) | 0.39 (0.892) | 0.27 (0.782) | 3.52 (0.782) | −0.010 (0.314) | −0.076 (0.601) | −0.022 (0.566) | 0.024 (0.829) | −0.071 (0.758) | 0.034 (0.402) | 0.48 (0.611) | −0.068 (0.602) | 0.016 (0.398) | 61.03% |
8 (90 days) | 0.022 (0.68) | 0.13 (0.667) | 0.075 (0.526) | 3.90 (0.630) | −0.004 (0.200) | −0.038 (0.521) | 0.0096 (0.101) | 0.012 (0.388) | −0.032 (0.536) | 0.055 (0.533) | 0.74 (0.869) | −0.033 (0.441) | 0.010 (0.301) | 35.11% |
9 (150 days) | 0.019 (0.59) | 0.025 (0.569) | 0.063 (0.482) | 3.11 (0.601) | −0.005 (0.211) | −0.035 (0.473) | 0.027 (0.76) | 0.008 (0.277) | −0.022 (0.506) | 0.083 (0.791) | 0.84 (0.98) | −0.021 (0.298) | 0.007 (0.211) | 23.26% |
10 (365 days) | 0.010 (0.44) | 0.035 (0.501) | 0.022 (0.273) | 1.36 (0.324) | 0.007 (0.38) | 0.013 (0.282) | 0.016 (0.49) | 0.004 (0.112) | 0.069 (0.322) | 0.13 (0.977) | 0.90 (1.00) | −0.015 (0.112) | 0.005 (0.109) | 13.29% |
Note(s): This table presents the average of risk coefficients over time, derived from monthly cross-sectional regression analyses as outlined in Equation (11). Panel A details regression results for 3,100 firms listed in Datastream, with all idiosyncratic risk measures calculated based on a 60-day period from January 1988 to June 2019. Panel B provides robustness checks for Equation (11), using various formation periods of 30, 90, 150, and 365 days for the idiosyncratic risk factors. Below each coefficient estimate, the table shows the percentage of coefficients that are statistically significant at the 5% level and have the same direction as the average coefficient
Source(s): Created by the author
Descriptive statistics of portfolios sorted into idiosyncratic risk measures
Portfolio | Panel A: IE | Panel B: IS | Panel C: IV | Panel D: IK | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Mean | IE | Carhart alpha | Mean | IS | Carhart alpha | Mean | IV | Carhart alpha | Mean | IK | Carhart alpha | |
1 (Low) | 1.09 | 0.06 | 1.19 (3.73)* | 0.92 | 0.04 | 1.00 (3.40)* | 1.02 | 0.011 | 0.98 (3.22)* | −1.20 | 0.82 | −1.21 (−3.88)* |
2 | 0.90 | 0.11 | 0.98 (2.33)* | −1.11 | 0.16 | −1.02 (−2.80)* | −1.01 | 0.015 | −1.00 (−3.01)* | −0.89 | 1.17 | −1.17 (−3.35)* |
3 | 0.69 | 0.12 | 0.74 (1.98)** | −1.14 | 0.18 | −1.12 (−2.99)* | −1.08 | 0.019 | −1.06 (−3.05)* | −0.92 | 1.47 | −1.20 (−3.47)* |
4 | −1.08 | 0.17 | −1.14 (−3.21)* | −1.19 | 0.26 | −1.14 (−3.14)* | −1.14 | 0.021 | −1.17 (−3.59)* | −1.00 | 2.00 | −1.26 (−3.55)* |
5 (High) | −1.33 | 0.31 | −1.28 (−3.69)* | −1.20 | 0.40 | −1.23 (−3.25)* | −1.20 | 0.039 | −1.22 (−3.49)* | 0.97 | 4.03 | 1.00 (2.37)* |
5–1 | −2.42 (−4.49)* | −2.47 (−4.46)* | −2.12 (−4.00)* | −2.23 (−4.06)* | −2.22 (−4.11)* | −2.10 (−4.10)* | 2.17 (3.33)* | 2.21 (3.44)* |
Note(s): We calculate the estimates
Source(s): Created by the author
FM regressions
Regressors | Models | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | 6 | 7 | |
Constant | 0.12 (1.00) | 0.11 (1.79)*** | 0.12 (0.88) | 0.13 (1.19) | 0.13 (0.77) | 0.20 (0.73) | 0.21 (0.70) |
−0.66 (−4.25)* | −0.66 (−4.05)* | −0.43 (−3.40)* | −0.33 (−3.01)* | ||||
−1.03 (−8.24)* | −0.98 (−7.79)* | −0.90 (−6.94)* | |||||
−0.22 (−3.02)* | −0.15 (−2.96)* | −0.11 (−2.72)* | |||||
5.22 (15.17)* | 5.22 (15.16)* | 3.44 (12.34)* | |||||
−0.13 (−3.93)* | −0.10 (−2.45)* | ||||||
0.061 (3.01)* | 0.041 (1.92)*** | ||||||
−0.11 (−3.66)* | −0.09 (−3.33)* | ||||||
−0.0022 (−0.44) | −0.002 (−0.40) | ||||||
−0.16 (−4.22)* | −0.14 (−3.96)* | ||||||
−0.93 (−6.18)* | −0.89 (−6.12)* | ||||||
−0.069 (−3.22)* | −0.064 (−3.09)* | ||||||
−0.009 (−1.11) | −0.008 (−1.00) | ||||||
74.25 [0.00] | 133.12 [0.00] | 63.12 [0.00] | 188.16 [0.00] | 592.14 [0.00] | 844.22 [0.00] | 992.28 [0.00] | |
Pricing error | 0.035 | 0.029 | 0.04 | 0.018 | 0.0086 | 0.0052 | 0.0033 |
Adj | 0.029 | 0.041 | 0.027 | 0.089 | 0.17 | 0.30 | 0.39 |
Note(s): This table outlines the results from the Fama and MacBeth (1973) regressions, along with their average coefficients, as per Equation (13). We analyze 100 portfolios that are sorted each month according to
Source(s): Created by the author
Robustness checks on FM regressions
Regressors | Panel A: formation periods | Panel B: number of portfolios | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
30 | 90 | 150 | 365 | 50 | 200 | |
Constant | 0.21 (0.72) | 0.22 (0.79) | 0.22 (0.84) | 0.20 (0.63) | 0.19 (0.70) | 0.20 (0.69) |
−0.70 (−5.66)* | −0.71 (−5.87)* | −0.67 (−5.15)* | −0.45 (−4.92)* | −0.33 (−4.08)* | −0.44 (−4.72)* | |
−0.71 (−6.35)* | −0.96 (−7.12)* | −0.39 (−3.68)* | −0.45 (−3.76)* | −0.89 (−6.66)* | −0.91 (−6.55)* | |
−0.39 (−3.44)* | −0.16 (−2.83)* | −0.13 (−2.81)* | −0.099 (−2.18)* | −0.09 (−1.93)*** | −0.16 (−2.84)* | |
3.50 (12.03)* | 2.78 (9.74)* | 3.93 (13.01)* | 4.77 (17.88)* | 2.16 (9.43)* | 3.88 (13.12)* | |
−0.13 (−2.99)* | −0.12 (−2.45)* | −0.12 (−2.66)* | −0.11 (−2.01)** | −0.13 (−2.33)** | −0.27 (−3.05)* | |
0.015 (0.84) | 0.046 (2.45)* | 0.04 (2.14)** | 0.038 (1.66) | 0.028 (1.78)*** | 0.036 (1.77)*** | |
−0.18 (−3.22)* | −0.26 (−3.33)* | −0.24 (−3.22)* | −0.24 (−3.44)* | −0.11 (−2.53)* | −0.16 (−2.78)* | |
−0.0036 (−1.33) | −0.0012 (−0.41) | −0.0028 (−1.11) | −0.006 (−2.54)* | −0.0038 (−0.49) | −0.016 (−0.84) | |
−0.12 (−3.99)* | −0.16 (−3.94)* | −0.19 (−3.93)* | −0.23 (−4.08)* | −0.11 (−2.36)* | −0.16 (−4.01)* | |
−0.80 (−5.43)* | −0.92 (−5.99)* | −0.95 (−6.04)* | −0.96 (−5.88)* | −0.79 (−5.34)* | −0.95 (−5.96)* | |
−0.060 (−2.91)* | −0.067 (−2.99)* | −0.081 (−3.86)* | −0.084 (−3.93)* | −0.054 (−2.52)* | −0.079 (−3.73)* | |
−0.007 (−0.88) | −0.009 (−0.99) | −0.011 (−1.12) | −0.012 (−1.19) | −0.006 (−0.69) | −0.010 (−1.01) | |
962.15 [0.00] | 994.22 [0.00] | 1014.06 [0.00] | 1008.33 [0.00] | 977.22 [0.00] | 999.26 [0.00] | |
Pricing error | 0.0036 | 0.0030 | 0.0026 | 0.0028 | 0.0034 | 0.0029 |
Adj | 0.34 | 0.38 | 0.44 | 0.43 | 0.36 | 0.41 |
Note(s): This table presents the results of the Fama and MacBeth (1973) regressions and their mean coefficients using equation (13). It utilizes monthly sorted portfolios based on
Source(s): Created by the author
Time-series determinates of entropy pricing
Statistics | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Estimations | 0.31 (0.08) | −0.37 (−0.23) | −0.96 (−0.40) | −1.28 (−0.46) | 2.09 (1.82)*** | −1.79 (−0.74) |
N = 3100 firms | R2 = 0.34 |
Note(s): This table presents the outcomes of Equation (17). To ensure accuracy, we have adjusted the standard errors of this model to consider the generated regressors as per Pagan (1984) and Shanken (1992), along with the time-series correlation methods outlined by Newey and West (1987). The symbol *** indicates that the results are statistically significant at the 10% level
Source(s): Created by the author
FM regressions on individual stocks
Regressors | Models | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | 6 | 7 | |
Constant | 0.12 (1.10) | 0.10 (3.66)* | 0.12 (0.83) | 0.11 (1.16) | 0.13 (0.80) | 0.22 (0.81) | 0.22 (0.82) |
−0.40 (−5.22)* | −0.38 (−4.98)* | −0.36 (−5.25)* | −0.30 (−4.42)* | ||||
−1.20 (−7.96)* | −1.15 (−7.66)* | −0.88 (−9.88)* | |||||
−0.30 (−3.71)* | −0.12 (−3.00)* | −0.44 (−4.32)* | |||||
3.44 (11.08)* | 3.26 (10.79)* | 2.80 (11.99)* | |||||
−0.096 (−2.42)* | −0.098 (−2.34)* | ||||||
0.07 (3.66)* | 0.027 (1.89) | ||||||
−0.16 (−3.62)* | −0.13 (−3.45)* | ||||||
−0.006 (−2.24)** | −0.005 (−1.98)** | ||||||
−0.13 (−3.93)* | −0.11 (−3.77)* | ||||||
−0.91 (−5.32)* | −0.86 (−5.04)* | ||||||
−0.07 (−3.42)* | −0.067 (−3.74)* | ||||||
−0.01 (−1.33) | −0.009 (−1.12) | ||||||
515.10 [0.00] | 577.22 [0.00] | 126.22 [0.00] | 98.24 [0.00] | 600.25 [0.00] | 766.08 [0.00] | 892.14 [0.00] | |
Pricing error | 0.0079 | 0.0069 | 0.029 | 0.039 | 0.0065 | 0.0054 | 0.004 |
Adj | 0.09 | 0.15 | 0.070 | 0.052 | 0.22 | 0.35 | 0.43 |
Note(s): This table displays the results of the Fama and MacBeth (1973) regressions, including their average coefficients as per Equation (18). These regressions are performed at the end of each month for the period from January 1988 to June 2019, using our sample. The measures
Source(s): Created by the author
FM regressions on IS- and IV-sorted portfolios
Regressors | Panel A: IV | Panel B: IS | ||||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | 6 | 7 | 1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | 6 | 7 | |
Constant | 0.12 (0.98) | 0.10 (2.50)* | 0.11 (1.02) | 0.11 (1.15) | 0.13 (1.07) | 0.21 (0.84) | 0.22 (0.80) | 0.11 (1.22) | 0.09 (1.72) | 0.09 (1.35) | 0.11 (1.95)*** | 0.12 (0.48) | 0.20 (0.72) | 0.20 (0.63) |
−0.68 (−5.33)* | −0.89 (−5.52)* | −0.66 (−5.36)* | −0.68 (−5.52)* | −0.62 (−4.66)* | −0.68 (−5.35)* | −0.60 (−5.67)* | −0.45 (−4.83)* | |||||||
−0.42 (−3.12)* | −0.13 (−1.32) | −0.40 (−3.72)* | −0.92 (−6.12)* | −0.48 (−3.3)* | −0.45 (−3.66)* | |||||||||
−0.38 (−2.9)* | −0.32 (−3.77)* | −0.13 (−3.74)* | −0.32 (−3.40)* | −0.11 (−2.52)* | −0.095 (−1.98)** | |||||||||
6.35 (6.34)* | 5.14 (5.33)* | 4.01 (4.33)* | 5.99 (5.55)* | 5.01 (3.89)* | 4.73 (3.26)* | |||||||||
−0.13 (−2.41)* | −0.13 (−2.61)* | −0.13 (−3.06)* | −0.12 (−2.2)** | |||||||||||
0.048 (2.62)* | 0.039 (2.12)** | 0.049 (2.55)* | 0.04 (1.65) | |||||||||||
−0.18 (−4.94)* | −0.24 (−6.88)* | −0.25 (−3.32)* | −0.20 (−3.24)* | |||||||||||
−0.005 (−1.99)** | −0.003 (−1.26) | −0.003 (−1.22) | −0.006 (−2.53)* | |||||||||||
−0.11 (−3.14)* | −0.11 (−3.14)* | −0.13 (−3.15)* | −0.11 (−3.21)* | |||||||||||
−1.05 (−5.68)* | −0.97 (−5.06)* | −0.98 (−5.92)* | −0.99 (−5.99)* | |||||||||||
−0.064 (−3.12)* | −0.06 (−3.01)* | −0.06 (−3.21)* | −0.05 (−3.01)* | |||||||||||
−0.008 (−1.05) | −0.007 (−0.95) | −0.007 (−0.98) | −0.006 (−0.89) | |||||||||||
555.10 [0.00] | 31.25 [0.04] | 14018 [0.00] | 510.22 [0.00] | 615.30 [0.00] | 809.02 [0.00] | 921.29 [0.00] | 498.44 [0.00] | 52.14 [0.03] | 86.14 [0.00] | 500.29 [0.00] | 555.21 [0.00] | 762.16 [0.00] | 894.15 [0.00] | |
Pricing error | 0.0092 | 0.078 | 0.033 | 0.0088 | 0.0071 | 0.005 | 0.0035 | 0.0080 | 0.057 | 0.044 | 0.009 | 0.0086 | 0.0062 | 0.0041 |
Adj | 0.14 | 0.0028 | 0.056 | 0.11 | 0.21 | 0.40 | 0.45 | 0.11 | 0.013 | 0.043 | 0.10 | 0.18 | 0.35 | 0.43 |
Note(s): This analysis follows the same methodology as in Table 4, with the only difference being that we now organize stocks into 100 portfolios each month based on IV. The outcomes of these IV-based pricing regressions are presented in Panel A. Following this, we apply the same categorization process using IS and display the results of the IS-based pricing regressions in Panel B. The symbols *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. The Fama-MacBeth (FM) t-statistics and the results of the
Source(s): Created by the author
Descriptive statistics of portfolios sorted into IV
Portfolio | 1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | 6 | 7 | 8 | 9 | 10 | 11 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Mean | Std. Dev | Skew | Entropy | IV | IE | IS | IK | Size | CAPM alpha | FF alpha | |
1 (Low) | 1.18 | 0.012 | 0.013 | 0.12 | 0.014 | 0.07 | 0.11 | 2.89 | 12.88 | 1.24 (4.82)* | 1.11 (4.35)* |
2 | 1.00 | 0.012 | 0.015 | 0.15 | 0.019 | 0.09 | 0.17 | 1.90 | 12.24 | 0.33 (2.47)* | 0.29 (2.52)* |
3 | −1.02 | 0.012 | 0.031 | 0.17 | 0.14 | 0.12 | 0.23 | 1.68 | 11.88 | −0.04 (−1.88)*** | −0.03 (−1.85)*** |
4 | −1.06 | 0.012 | 0.24 | 0.22 | 0.28 | 0.17 | 0.28 | 1.82 | 10.99 | −1.22 (−2.93)* | −1.15 (−2.89)* |
5 (High) | −1.29 | 0.011 | 0.28 | 0.34 | 0.40 | 0.28 | 0.34 | 1.64 | 8.22 | −1.42 (−3.77)* | −1.36 (−3.38)* |
5–1 | −2.47 (−4.45)* | −2.66 (−4.30)* | −2.47 (−4.56)* |
Note(s): This table displays descriptive statistics for portfolios categorized by IV. We calculate the
Source(s): Created by the author
Robustness checks: FM regressions on alternative entropy measures
Regressors | Panel A: Renyi’s entropy | Panel B: Tsallis’s entropy | Panel C: Kullback and Leibler’s entropy |
---|---|---|---|
Constant | 0.13 (0.59) | 0.15 (0.57) | 0.07 (0.27) |
−0.35 (−3.08)* | −0.41 (−3.66)* | −0.16 (−2.74)* | |
−0.76 (−5.77)* | −0.83 (−5.98)* | −0.58 (−3.87)* | |
−0.12 (−2.72)* | −0.27 (−2.93) | −0.08 (−1.77)*** | |
3.11 (12.74)* | 3.35 (12.66)* | 1.80 (5.00)* | |
−0.18 (−2.44)** | −0.35 (−3.98)* | −0.048 (−1.91)*** | |
0.031 (1.54) | 0.046 (1.55) | 0.006 (0.94) | |
−0.12 (−2.22)** | −0.27 (−3.82)* | −0.06 (−1.32) | |
−0.011 (−0.78) | −0.017 (−0.77) | −0.002 (−0.62) | |
−0.12 (−3.66)* | −0.23 (−3.93)* | −0.06 (−2.23)* | |
−0.80 (−4.53)* | −0.97 (−5.43)* | −0.39 (−2.77)* | |
−0.077 (−3.55)* | −0.082 (−3.63)* | −0.065 (−2.97)* | |
−0.010 (−1.08) | −0.011 (−1.15) | −0.008 (−0.85) | |
990.22 [0.00] | 997.21 [0.00] | 600.10 [0.00] | |
Pricing error | 0.0036 | 0.0033 | 0.0083 |
Adj | 0.37 | 0.39 | 0.17 |
Note(s): The methodology used here mirrors that of Table 4, with the only difference being the substitution of Shannon entropy (calculated using Equation (5) with Renyi’s collision entropy (Equation (14), Tsallis’s entropy (Equation (15), and Kullback and Leibler’s entropy (Equation (16)). We then replicate the same pricing analyses as those shown in Table 4. The symbols *, **, and *** represent statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. The Fama-MacBeth (FM) t-statistics and the
Source(s): Created by the author
Descriptive statistics of double-sorted portfolios
Portfolio | 1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | 6 | 7 | 8 | 9 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Mean | Std. Dev | Skew | Entropy | IV | IE | Size | CAPM alpha | FF alpha | |
Panel A: double-sorted IV portfolios | |||||||||
1 (Low) | 0.84 | 0.010 | −0.018 | 0.20 | 0.17 | 0.063 | 12.85 | 0.87 (3.48)* | 0.90 (3.30)* |
2 | 0.79 | 0.020 | 0.042 | 0.16 | 0.50 | 0.052 | 12.22 | 0.80 (3.16)* | 0.80 (3.15)* |
3 | −1.00 | 0.035 | 0.079 | 0.13 | 0.59 | 0.045 | 9.44 | −1.34 (−2.22)** | −1.30 (−2.12)** |
4 | −1.23 | 0.044 | 0.17 | 0.11 | 0.62 | 0.036 | 9.23 | −1.41 (−2.92)* | −1.32 (−2.77)* |
5 (High) | −1.25 | 0.112 | 0.26 | 0.08 | 0.67 | 0.031 | 7.33 | −1.50 (−2.96)* | −1.24 (−2.48)* |
5–1 | −2.09 (−3.08)* | −2.37 (−3.22)* | −2.14 (−3.16)* | ||||||
UMC | −0.32 (−2.25)** | −0.20 (−2.15)** | −0.23 (−2.26)* | ||||||
Panel B: double-sorted IE portfolios | |||||||||
1 (Low) | 0.86 | 0.012 | 0.11 | 0.075 | 0.40 | 0.044 | 12.48 | 0.88 (3.18)* | 0.90 (3.23)* |
2 | 0.82 | 0.020 | 0.09 | 0.14 | 0.50 | 0.049 | 11.77 | 0.74 (3.16)* | 0.60 (2.89)* |
3 | −0.98 | 0.078 | 0.081 | 0.17 | 0.52 | 0.054 | 10.34 | −1.23 (−2.11)** | −1.06 (−1.78)*** |
4 | −1.18 | 0.083 | 0.071 | 0.23 | 0.64 | 0.058 | 9.09 | −1.28 (−2.18)** | −1.19 (−1.96)*** |
5 (High) | −1.30 | 0.090 | 0.109 | 0.27 | 0.72 | 0.066 | 7.66 | −1.38 (−2.27)** | −1.35 (−2.01)** |
5–1 | −2.16 (−3.20)* | −2.26 (−3.26)* | −2.25 (−3.22)* | ||||||
UMC | −0.28 (−2.22)** | −0.20 (−2.15)** | −0.23 (−2.26)* |
Note(s): This table displays detailed statistics for portfolios arranged by expected entropy and IV. Each month, from January 1988 to June 2019, we calculate the
Source(s): Created by the author
Descriptive statistics of portfolios were sorted into idiosyncratic risk measures
Panel A: 90-day formation period | Panel B: 180-day formation period | Panel C: 365-day formation period | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Mean | IE | Carhart alpha | Mean | IE | Carhart alpha | Mean | IE | Carhart alpha | |
1 (Low) | 1.06 | 0.05 | 1.10 (3.53)* | 1.00 | 0.06 | 1.04 (3.34)* | 0.89 | 0.08 | 0.93 (3.00)* |
2 | 0.86 | 0.15 | 0.91 (2.17)** | 0.92 | 0.16 | 0.81 (2.01)** | 0.77 | 0.18 | 0.79 (1.92)*** |
3 | 0.60 | 0.18 | 0.68 (1.77)*** | 0.53 | 0.22 | 0.60 (1.68)*** | 0.43 | 0.26 | 0.49 (1.38) |
4 | −1.12 | 0.19 | −1.19 (−3.31)* | −1.02 | 0.24 | −1.10 (−3.20)* | −1.00 | 0.23 | −1.03 (−3.07)* |
5 (High) | −1.24 | 0.33 | −1.26 (−3.57)* | −1.12 | 0.30 | −1.15 (−3.66)* | −1.10 | 0.34 | −1.12 (−3.71)* |
5–1 | −2.20 (−4.02)* | −2.36 (−4.30)* | −2.12 (−3.55)* | −2.19 (−3.68)* | −1.99 (−2.22)** | −2.05 (−2.29)* |
Note(s): We construct the estimates
Source(s): Created by the author
Notes
The IV puzzle has attracted considerable attention among researchers, a fact highlighted by notable studies such as those conducted by Lee and Mauck (2016) and Aabo, Pantzalis, and Park (2017).
To prove this rule, see Taylor (1952).
Shannon and Weaver (1964) have clarified why the logarithmic form is used in entropy calculations. It’s important to note that since the logarithm of a fraction is negative and the probability
Panel D in Figure 1 also shows similar results, indicating that episodes of high IV and high IV dispersion align with the findings of Brandt, Brav, Graham, and Kumar (2008). They describe these times as “speculative periods.”
Maximum (MAX) is the maximum daily return within a month by using
We carried out thorough checks to verify the appropriateness of our chosen formation period and found consistent results across various periods, including 30, 90, 150, and 365 days for IE formation. These findings are detailed in subsection (4.3.1).
The results of these checks are not reported in this paper and are available on request.
The results are not reported in this paper and are available on request.
The results are not reported due to space restrictions and are available on request.
While various values of α are employed in academic studies, both Principe (2010) and Chernyshov (2012) demonstrate that setting α to 2 leads to favorable outcomes in empirical research.
Return entropy comprises both IE and additional co-entropy elements. While Table 2 indicates that IV is a predictor of IE, further investigation is required to ascertain whether IV can also forecast co-entropy returns. This aspect is earmarked for exploration in future research.
Reference
Aabo, T., Pantzalis, C., & Park, J. C. (2017). Idiosyncratic volatility: An indicator of noise trading?. Journal of Banking and Finance, 75, 136–151. doi: 10.1016/j.jbankfin.2016.11.003.
Amaya, D., Christoffersen, P., Jacobs, K., & Vasquez, A. (2015). Does realized skewness predict the cross-section of equity returns?. Journal of Financial Economics, 118(1), 135–167. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2015.02.009.
Ang, A., Hodrick, R. J., Xing, Y., & Zhang, X. (2006). The cross-section of volatility and expected returns. Journal of Finance, 61(1), 259–299. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.00836.x.
Ang, A., Hodrick, R., Xing, Y., & Zhang, X. (2009). High idiosyncratic volatility and low returns: International and further U.S. Evidence. Journal of Financial Economics, 91(1), 1–23. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2007.12.005.
Backus, D., Chernov, M., & Martin, I. (2011). Disasters implied by equity index options. The Journal of Finance, LXVI(6), 1969–2012. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2011.01697.x.
Backus, D., Boyarchenko, N., & Chernov, M. (2018). Term structures of asset prices and returns. Journal of Financial Economics, 129(1), 1–23. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2018.04.005.
Bali, T. G., Cakici, N., & Whitelaw, R. F. (2011). Maxing out: Stocks as lotteries and the cross-section of expected returns. Journal of Financial Economics, 99(2), 427–446. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.08.014.
Barberis, N., & Huang, M. (2008). Stocks as lotteries: The implications of probability weighting for security prices. American Economic Review, 98(5), 2066–2100. doi: 10.1257/aer.98.5.2066.
Benedetto, F., Giunta, G., & Mastroeni, L. (2016). On the predictability of energy commodity markets by an entropy-based computational method. Energy Economics, 54, 302–312. doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2015.12.009.
Billio, M., Casarin, R., Costola, M., & Pasqualini, A. (2016). An entropy-based early warning indicator for systemic risk. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, 45, 42–59. doi: 10.1016/j.intfin.2016.05.008.
Boehme, R. D., Danielsen, B. R., Kumar, P., & Sorescu, S. (2009). Idiosyncratic risk and the cross-section of stock returns: Merton (1987) meets miller (1977). Journal of Financial Markets, 12(3), 438–468. doi: 10.1016/j.finmar.2009.01.004.
Boyer, B., Mitton, T., & Vorkink, K. (2010). Expected idiosyncratic skewness. Review of Financial Studies, 23(1), 169–202. doi: 10.1093/rfs/hhp041.
Brandt, M. W., Brav, A., Graham, J. R., & Kumar, A. (2008). The idiosyncratic volatility puzzle: Time trend or speculative episodes?. Review of Financial Studies, 23(2), 863–899. doi: 10.1093/rfs/hhp087.
Brunnermeier, M., Gollier, C., & Parker, J. (2007). Optimal beliefs, asset prices and the preference for skewed returns. In American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 97(2), 159–65. doi: 10.1257/aer.97.2.159.
Busch, T., Christensen, B. J., & Nielsen, M. Q. (2011). The role of implied volatility in forecasting future realized volatility and jumps in foreign exchange, stock, and bond markets. Journal of Econometrics, 160(1), 48–57. doi: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2010.03.014.
Calomiris, C. W., & Mamaysky, H. (2019). How news and its context drive risk and returns around the world. Journal of Financial Economics, 133(2), 299–336. doi: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2018.11.009.
Caplin, A., Dean, M., & Leahy, J. (2022). Rationally inattentive behavior: Characterizing and generalizing Shannon entropy. Journal of Political Economy, 130(6), 1676–1715. doi: 10.1086/719276.
Carhart, M. M. (1997). On persistence of mutual fund performance. Journal of Finance, 52(1), 57–82. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1997.tb03808.x.
Chen, J., Hong, H., & Stein, J. (2001). Forecasting crashes: Trading volume, past returns, and conditional skewness in stock prices. Journal of Financial Economics, 61(3), 345–81. doi: 10.1016/s0304-405x(01)00066-6.
Chernov, M., Graveline, J., & Zviadadze, I. (2018). Crash risk in currency returns. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 53(1), 137–170. doi: 10.1017/s0022109017000801.
Chernyshov, K. R. (2012). Statistical linearization of multivariable systems with a criterion based on the rényi entropy. In IFAC Proceedings Volumes (Vol. 45 16 pp. 185–190). doi: 10.3182/20120711-3-be-2027.00411.
Conrad, J., Dittmar, R. F., & Ghysels, E. (2013). Ex ante Skewness and Expected Stock Returns. The Journal of Finance, LXVIII(1), 85–124. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2012.01795.x.
Cressie, N. A. C. (1993). Statistics for spatial data. New York: Wiley.
Darbellay, G. A., & Wuertz, D. (2000). The entropy as a tool for analysing statistical dependences in financial time series. Physica A, 287(3-4), 429–439. doi: 10.1016/s0378-4371(00)00382-4.
Dimpfl, T., & Peter, F. (2018). Analyzing volatility transmission using group transfer entropy. Energy Economics, 75, 368–376. doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2018.08.008.
Ebrahimi, N., Maasoumi, E., & Soofi, E. (1999). Comparison of entropy and variance orderings. Journal of Econometrics, 90(2), 317–336. doi: 10.1016/s0304-4076(98)00046-3.
Fama, E., & French, K. (1993). Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of Financial Economics, 33(1), 3–56. doi: 10.1016/0304-405x(93)90023-5.
Fama, E., & MacBeth, M. J. (1973). Risk, return, and equilibrium: Empirical tests. Journal of Political Economy, 81(3), 607–636. doi: 10.1086/260061.
Fleming, J., Ostdiek, B., & Whaley, R. E. (1995). Predicting stock market volatility: A new measure. The Journal of Future Markets, 15(3), 265–302. doi: 10.1002/fut.3990150303.
Ghosh, A., Julliard, C., & Taylor, A. P. (2017). What is the consumption-CAPM missing? An information theoretic framework for the analysis of asset pricing models. The Review of Financial Studies, 30(2), 442–504. doi: 10.1093/rfs/hhw075.
Glasserman, P., & Mamaysky, H. (2019). Does unusual news forecast market stress?. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 54(5), 1937–1974. doi: 10.47473/2020rmm0038.
Gulko, L. (1999). The entropy theory of stock option pricing. International Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance, 2(03), 331–355. doi: 10.1142/s0219024999000182.
Gulko, L. (2002). The entropy theory of bond option pricing. International Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance, 5(4), 355–383. doi: 10.1142/s021902490200147x.
Harvey, C. R., & Siddique, A. (2000). Conditional skewness in asset pricing tests. Journal of Finance, 55(3), 1263–1295. doi: 10.1111/0022-1082.00247.
Holm, J. (1993). Maximum entropy lorenz curves. Journal of Econometrics, 59(3), 377–389. doi: 10.1016/0304-4076(93)90031-y.
Jaynes, E. T. (1965). Gibbs vs Boltzmann entropies. American Journal of Physics, 33(5), 391–398. doi: 10.1119/1.1971557.
Jiang, G. J., Xu, D., & Yao, T. (2009). The information content of idiosyncratic volatility. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 44, 1–28. doi: 10.1017/s0022109009090073.
Jiang, L., Wu, K., & Zhou, G. (2018). Asymmetry in stock comovements: An entropy approach. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 53(4), 1479–1507. doi: 10.1017/s0022109018000340.
Kraus, A., & Litzenberger, R. (1976). Skewness preference and the valuation of risk assets. Journal of Finance, 31(4), 1085–100. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1976.tb01961.x.
Kristoufek, L., & Vosvrda, M. (2014). Commodity futures and market efficiency. Energy Economics, 42, 50–57. doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2013.12.001.
Kullback, S., & Leibler, R. A. (1951). On information and sufficiency. The Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 22(1), 79–86. doi: 10.1214/aoms/1177729694.
Lee, B. S., & Mauck, N. (2016). Dividend initiations, increases and idiosyncratic volatility. Journal of Corporate Finance, 40, 47–60. doi: 10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2016.07.005.
Maasoumi, M. (1993). A compendium to information theory in economics and econometrics. Econometric Reviews, 12(2), 137–181. doi: 10.1080/07474939308800260.
Maasoumi, E., & Racine, J. (2002). Entropy and predictability of stock market returns. Journal of Econometrics, 107(1-2), 291–312. doi: 10.1016/s0304-4076(01)00125-7.
Maasoumi, E., & Theil, H. (1979). The effect of the shape of the income distribution on two inequality measures. Economics Letters, 4(3), 289–291. doi: 10.1016/0165-1765(79)90152-6.
Martina, E., Rodriguez, E., Escarela-Perez, R., & Alvarez-Ramirez, J. (2011). Multiscale entropy analysis of crude oil price dynamics. Energy Economics, 33(5), 936–947. doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2011.03.012.
Mukherjee, D., & Ratnaparkhi, M. V. (1986). On the functional relationship between entropy and variance with related applications. Communications in Statistics-Theory and Methods, 15(1), 291–311. doi: 10.1080/03610928608829122.
Newey, W., & West, K. (1987). A simple, positive definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica, 55(3), 703–708. doi: 10.2307/1913610.
Oh, G., Kim, S., & Eom, C. (2007). Market efficiency in foreign exchange markets. Physica A, 382(1), 209–212. doi: 10.1016/j.physa.2007.02.032.
Ortiz-Cruz, A., Rodriguez, E., Ibarra-Valdez, C., & Alvarez-Ramirez, J. (2012). Efficiency of crude oil markets: Evidences from informational entropy analysis. Energy Policy, 41, 365–373. doi: 10.1016/j.enpol.2011.10.057.
Pagan, A. (1984). Econometric issues in the analysis of regressions with generated regressors. International Economic Review, 25(1), 221–247. doi: 10.2307/2648877.
Pastor, L., & Stambaugh, R. F. (2003). Liquidity risk and expected stock returns. Journal of Political Economy, 111(3), 642–685. doi: 10.1086/374184.
Philippatos, G. C., & Wilson, C. J. (1972). Entropy, market risk, and the selection of efficient portfolios. Applied Economics, 4(3), 209–220. doi: 10.1080/00036847200000017.
Principe, J. C. (2010). Information theoretic learning. New York, Dordrecht, Heidelberg, London: Springer.
Renyi, A. (1961). On measures of entropy and information. In Fourth berkeley symposium on mathematical statistics and probability, (pp. 547–561). Berkeley, Calif: University of California Press.
Risso, W. A. (2008). The informational efficiency and the financial crashes. Research in International Business and Finance, 22(3), 396–408. doi: 10.1016/j.ribaf.2008.02.005.
Risso, W. A. (2009). The informational efficiency: The emerging markets versus the developed markets. Applied Economics Letters, 16(5), 485–487. doi: 10.1080/17446540802216219.
Rubinstein, M. (1973). The fundamental theory of parameter-preference security valuation. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 8(1), 61–9. doi: 10.2307/2329748.
Shanken, J. (1992). On the estimation of beta-pricing models. Review of Financial Studies, 5, 1–33. doi: 10.1093/rfs/5.1.1.
Shannon, C. E. (1948). A mathematical theory of communication. Bell System Technical Journal, 27(4), 379–423. doi: 10.1002/j.1538-7305.1948.tb00917.x.
Shannon, C. E., & Weaver, W. (1964). The mathematical theory of communication. Urbana: University of Illinois Press.
Taylor, A. E. (1952). L'Hospital's rule. The American Mathematical Monthly, 59(1), 20–24. doi: 10.1080/00029890.1952.11988058.
Tsallis, C. (1988). Generalized entropy-based criterion for consistent testing, Physical Review E Scope, 58, 1442–1445.
Usta, I., & Kantar, Y. M. (2011). Mean-variance-skewness-entropy measures: A multi-objective approach for portfolio selection. Entropy, 13(1), 117–133. doi: 10.3390/e13010117.