Abstract
Purpose
We propose an economic model of housing markets. The model incorporates the macroeconomic relationships between prices, demand and supply. Since vacancy rates are not observable, the demand-supply mismatches are identified using a microeconomic model of search, matching and price formation. The model is applied to data on regional housing markets in England and Wales.
Design/methodology/approach
Economic theory combining macroeconomics and microeconomics together with new generation econometric methods for empirical analysis.
Findings
The empirical model, estimated for the ten government office regions of England and Wales, validates the economic model. We find that there is substantial heterogeneity across the regions, which is useful in informing housing and land-use policies. In addition to heterogeneity, the model enables us to better understand unrestricted inter-regional spatial relationships. The estimated spatial autocorrelations imply different drivers of spatial diffusion in different regions.
Research limitations/implications
In the nature of other empirical work, the findings are subject to specificities of the data considered here. The understanding of spatial diffusion can also be further developed in future work.
Practical implications
This paper develops a nice way of closing macroeconomic models of housing markets when complete demand, supply and pricing data are not available. The model may also be useful when data are available but with large measurement errors. The model comes together with corresponding empirical methods.
Social implications
Implications for the housing market and other regional policies are important. These are context-specific, but some implications for housing policy in the UK are provided in the paper as an example.
Originality/value
Unique housing market paper combining both macroeconomic and microeconomic theory as well as both theory and empirics. The rich framework so developed can be extended to much future work.
Keywords
Citation
Bhattacharjee, A. and Jensen-Butler, C. (2024), "A model of regional housing markets in England and Wales", Asian Journal of Economics and Banking, Vol. 8 No. 2, pp. 146-161. https://doi.org/10.1108/AJEB-03-2024-0024
Publisher
:Emerald Publishing Limited
Copyright © 2024, Arnab Bhattacharjee and Chris Jensen-Butler
License
Published in Asian Journal of Economics and Banking. Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode
1. Introduction
Much has been written about how residential property markets function at the macroeconomic level, including price formation and inflation, demographic change, unemployment and productivity, and volatility and speculative consumption or bubbles; see, for example, Meen (2008), Favilukis et al. (2017), Hsieh and Moretti (2019), Maclennan and Long (2024) and White (2024). A substantial part of this research has focussed on urban housing markets, attempting to understand demand-supply mismatches, price-elasticities of demand and supply, the process of price formation and temporal evolution of housing prices and their volatility; see, Bhattacharjee et al. (2024) for a review. In this paper, we examine the way in which housing markets in the ten government office regions (GORs) in England and Wales operate by constructing an economic model that incorporates both the macroeconomic relationships between demand, supply and prices as well as the microeconomic processes of search and matching in housing markets. The model admits completely unrestricted spatial heterogeneity and autocorrelation across the regions and can therefore inform place-based policy and interregional diffusion of demand.
The approach enables a better characterisation of key features of the UK housing market, such as volatility, supply-demand mismatches and ripple effects. The model is estimated using monthly data for the period November 2000–May 2003, on house prices, time-on-the-market and degree of overpricing together with regional data on economic activity and neighbourhood characteristics. The estimated model incorporates heterogeneity across the different regions in England and Wales. The methodology proposed can be used to study regions as a whole as well as sub-markets, facilitating comparison of the effects of different policies such as improvement of transport infrastructure, quality of public services and jobs-skills trajectories on the housing market, either at national or regional levels. The results have important implications for policy for the housing market as a whole and for various sub-markets.
The paper is organised as follows: Section 2 offers a selective review of the empirical literature on housing markets, focussing on the UK and discusses the institutional background. The proposed structural model is presented in Section 3, followed by a description of the econometric model, methodology and data in Section 4. Section 5 discusses the empirical findings and conclusions are drawn in Section 6.
2. Studies of the UK housing market and the institutional backdrop
A substantial body of literature on the UK housing market has accumulated over the past four decades. Research illustrates a strong growth in prices and high volatility, reflecting mismatch between demand and supply, at least in a localised context (in terms of region and type of housing, for example), an extremely low and declining price-elasticity of supply and a lower response of demand to price signals as compared with changes in income; see, for example, Meen (2003) and Barker (2004).
The literature also reflects substantial and continuing inter-regional differences, both in prices and volatility. These spatial price differentials have been attributed to differences in features of the local economies (Muellbauer and Murphy, 1997) as well as to local supply constraints that limit the response of prices to changes in the economic environment (Meen, 2001, 2003; Barker, 2003; Muellbauer, 2003). The implications of inter-regional differences in housing markets in terms of reduced mobility (Cameron and Muellbauer, 1998) and growing spatial inequality (Barker, 2003) are also discussed.
Two other aspects of the UK regional housing markets have attracted considerable recent research attention. First, several hedonic and repeated sales models of regional prices have been constructed (Holmans, 1990; Ashworth and Parker, 1997; Rosenthal, 1999; Anselin and Lozano-Gracia, 2009; Anselin et al., 2010; Bhattacharjee et al., 2016, 2017). These models reflect not only geographically varying price effects but also substantial spatial dependence. Second, a number of authors have also studied the so-called ripple effects, by which house prices have a propensity to first rise in the South-East during an upswing and then spread out to the rest of the UK over time (Meen, 1999; Cook and Holly, 2000; Cook, 2003; Bhattacharjee et al., 2022). The existence of ripple effects reflects spatio-temporal dependence in regional house prices in the UK.
The above-mentioned literature acknowledges implicitly the strong spatio-temporal dependence in features of regional/local housing markets. Attempts are made to explain spatial diffusion, particularly in terms of neighbourhood characteristics such as crime rates, schooling, transport infrastructure and quality of public services (Meen, 2001; Gibbons and Machin, 2003, 2005; Cheshire and Sheppard, 2004; Gibbons, 2004; Bhattacharjee and Jensen-Butler, 2013), and social interactions and segregation (Meen and Meen, 2003; Bhattacharjee and Jensen-Butler, 2013). In this paper, we do not hypothesize a priori any fixed pattern of spatial diffusion and instead we estimate our models in a way that is consistent with the observed pattern of spatial dependence.
As noted above, the extensive recent literature on the UK housing market demonstrates a substantial and persistent mismatch between demand and supply, an extremely low and declining price-elasticity of supply, a low response of demand to price signals, substantial and continuing inter-regional differences in prices and volatility and ripple effects; see, for example, Meen (1996, 2003). These spatial differences have been attributed to differences in features of the local economies as well as to local supply constraints that limit the behaviour of prices as a response to changes in the economic environment (Meen, 2003).
Our economic model rests upon microeconomic theoretical foundations and allows both for heterogeneity across the regions and unrestricted spatial diffusion. There is a large literature on econometric methods to estimate regression models with spatio-temporal variation, both with and without spatially distributed lags; see, for example, Elhorst (2003), Baltagi et al. (2003), Giacomini and Granger (2004) and Kelejian and Prucha (2004). Applying these methods, our estimated models derived from the above economic model are useful in understanding the factors driving the regional housing markets in the UK, including region-specific differences in economic activity and neighbourhood conditions.
3. A micro-founded model of housing markets
The economic model proposed here draws upon the literature on aggregate analysis of office space markets and on search and bargaining in market microstructure models of price-setting in residential housing markets.
3.1 Demand, supply and prices
Based broadly on research on rental office markets (Wheaton and Torto, 1993; Wheaton, 1990; Wheaton et al., 1997; Hendershott et al., 2002; Fuerst, 2004), we first consider an economic model consisting of three behavioural relationships (for price, demand and supply dynamics) linking exogenous variables to the housing market.
The price adjustment relationship (Relationship 1) relates rates of change in the realised value (price) (Vt) of housing properties to deviations of the vacancy rate (νt) from the natural vacancy rate (ν⋆) and deviations of the realised value from its equilibrium level
Demand (Dt) is modelled as a function of realised value, housing market conditions and neighbourhood characteristics (Relationship 2). The market conditions include economic activity (Yt – local and economy-wide income, unemployment, productivity and interest rates) and the neighbourhood characteristics include socioeconomic variables (Xt – quality of education and public services, crime, demographics, etc.).
In equilibrium, supply (St) is related to demand as
If vacancy rates (or occupancy rates) and supply were perfectly observed, the above three relationships (Equations (1), (2) and (3)) would form a recursive system and the structural relationships can be estimated (Hendershott et al., 2002). This is the usual approach taken in the rental office market literature.
However, quality data on vacancy rates for the residential housing market in the UK are difficult to source. Further, even though data on supply of residential property are more readily available, there may not be perceptible changes in supply over time in many non-urban areas since investment in residential property is often highly localised and geographically not very widespread. Hence, it is probable that supply data may not contain much information on the temporal variation in the demand-supply balance in regional housing markets.
3.2 Price-setting
Given these features of the residential housing market, we look into the literature on search, bargaining and price-setting in housing markets to identify other observed characteristics of the housing markets that may inform demand-supply mismatches.
The literature on search and bargaining models (Wheaton, 1990; Yavas, 1992; Arnold, 1999; Krainer, 2001; Anglin et al., 2003) highlights the way in which an initial list price is set, and the final (realised) price is determined through repeated search and bargaining by both the seller and the buyer, and the time-on-the-market that it takes to find a successful match. The trade-offs between time-on-the-market and setting the initial listing price (equivalently, the degree of overpricing) play important roles in this price-setting process. A higher list price
Broadly following Anglin et al. (2003), the degree of overpricing (DOPt) is modelled as follows:
Further, time-on-the-market will decrease with the degree of overpricing and increase with vacancy rate; this negative effect of the degree of overpricing on time-on-the-market may be magnified in a market niche with a smaller list price variance. We propose to use the price determination process and the relationship between time-on-the-market and degree of overpricing (Relationship 4) to identify the wedge between demand and supply in residential markets.
The above five relationships (Equations (1), (2), (3), (4) and (5)) describe our proposed micro-founded model of demand and supply in a regional housing market.
Following Anselin (1988, 2002), we model spatial variation using a spatial regime model that allows for unrestricted heterogeneity across the regions and a completely unrestricted pattern of spatial diffusion. In other words, our regression models are estimated based on flexible descriptions of spatial diffusion in both cross-regressive variables (spatially distributed lags) and spatial errors.
4. Econometric methodology
The structural parameters of the system of simultaneous equations given by the relationships above can be estimated in the presence of known spatial and temporal dependence. When vacancy rates and supply are observed, Relationships 1–3 form a recursive system. When these are observed imperfectly, as in our case, this information may be recovered from variation in time-on-the-market and degree of overpricing and the relationship between the two. The reduced form equations of the endogenous variables can be estimated and the structural parameters recovered. This, of course, is assuming that the spatial and temporal autocorrelation in the errors and the nature of spatially distributed lags have been modelled using an appropriate specification of the diffusion process.
4.1 Empirical model
We estimate our structural relationships in first differences. This renders each of demand, supply, prices, degree-of-overpricing and time on the market stationary across the temporal dimension, while nonstationary (or non-granular) and stationary dynamics over space can be modelled using spatial regression models with common factors (Pesaran and Tosetti, 2011; Bhattacharjee et al., 2022, 2024). Here we use a spatial regime model with heterogeneity across the regions and completely unrestricted (nonparametric) spatial autocorrelations.
Supply and demand both have temporal variation. Demand is endogenously determined but supply is exogenous, and we assume that the natural value
Growth of prices (realised value) is determined by growth rates of the occupancy rate (1 − vacancy rate or growth of demand relative to supply), natural value and (time-)lagged realised value. Since
In turn, demand growth is explained by change in local (neighbourhood characteristics), growth rate of house prices and change in (local) income or other demand side indicators for local market conditions:
Listing price,
Likewise, time on the market is modelled as:
Under this simple structure without spatial diffusion, and assuming that we have one measure for each of the exogenous variables, we examine the identifiability of the individual equations (relationships). Here we have four endogenous variables (Δ ln Vt, Δ ln Dt, Δ ln DOPt and ΔTOMt) and six exogenous or lagged endogenous variables (Δ ln Dt−1, Δ ln St−1, Δ ln Vt−1, ΔXt, Δ ln Yt and Δ ln St).
All four simultaneous equations are overidentified so that the structural parameters in each relationship can be recovered using two-stage least squares. Efficiency can be improved and weak identification mitigated by including multiple indicators for neighbourhood characteristics and local market conditions.
In addition to spatial heterogeneity, we model spatial autocorrelation or diffusion of demand shocks ϵ2t. Specifically, we allow spatial spillover of the shocks using a spatial error model with spatial autoregressive errors (Anselin, 1988, 1999, 2002). With the errors organised as a n × 1 vector e2 collecting values across the n regions, this model is written as:
4.2 Methodology
In the first stage of our estimation procedure, we estimate the four structural equations individually for each region. This allows for heterogeneity in the relationships across the regions, both in region or fixed effects (intercept heterogeneity) and slope heterogeneity, and in the relevant choice of indicators for neighbourhood characteristics and market conditions; in this final aspect, it has the flavour of high-dimensional model selection (Cai et al., 2019). In other words, we assume a spatial regime model (Anselin, 1988) with a completely general form of heterogeneity across the spatial units. This kind of heterogeneity is reasonable in our context, since our regions are large and it is expected a priori that the functioning of housing markets in different regions will be heterogeneous. Under this model, we estimate our structural equations separately for each region using two-stage least squares, and then combine these individual region-specific models, assuming a very general form of spatial diffusion.
For the errors, we assume a spatial autoregressive (SAR) model with an unspecified structure of spatial autocorrelations determined by an unknown spatial weights matrix. Following Fiebig (1999), we estimate the structural equation for demand using seemingly unrelated regressions (SURE) (Zellner, 1962) and recover the nonparametric estimate of the spatial covariance matrix of the reduced form errors from the first stage of this two-stage least squares procedure. As emphasized by Anselin (1999), this approach is very general and does not require any specification of spatial processes or any functional form for the distance decay. In other words, this estimation methodology is nonparametric and makes no assumption about the drivers of spatial diffusion in demand.
Thus, we place special emphasis on the spatial diffusion of demand, which is important in understanding the spatial structure of housing markets. If desired, a similar procedure can also be used to understand the nature of spatial externalities in prices, DOP and TOM.
4.3 Data
Our empirical analysis covers housing markets in England and Wales over the period November 2000–May 2003. Because of the distinct nature of the Scottish housing market, particularly in relation to price formation, Scotland is not included in the current analysis. The basic spatial units of analysis are the ten GORs [1] in England and Wales (Figure 1). Data on regional housing markets for the period were collected or estimated on a monthly basis.
Monthly data on local housing markets at three-digit postcode level were obtained from Hometrack, an independent property research and database company in the UK. The variables included are:
Average number of views;
Average time on the market (TOM) and
Average final to listing price ratios (reciprocal of DOP).
The Hometrack data are based on a compilation of monthly responses to a questionnaire from about 3,500 major estate agents in England and Wales. Like other survey-based housing market information in the UK, the reliability of these data depends critically on the representativeness of the selected estate agents, an issue that has not been addressed sufficiently in the literature. These data were used elsewhere (Bhattacharjee and Jensen-Butler, 2013) to study inter-regional spillovers in prices and housing demand.
For the purposes of the current paper, the data are unique in providing information on time on the market and degree-of-overpricing, which provide a unique opportunity to combine the macroeconomic dimension with the process of search, matching and price formation at the microeconomic level. The data also have good coverage in terms of both the spatial and temporal dimensions.
We validate the Hometrack data against related information from other sources. We also augment these data with quarterly information on sales price and number of sales by type of property for each county and local/unitary authority, collected from the HM Land Registry of England and Wales.
Additional regional spatio-temporal data were collected on various dimensions, including:
Supply: Housing stock (Source: Office of the Deputy Prime Minister (ODPM) and the Office of National Statistics (ONS));
Demand: Proportion of local authority and RSL dwellings having low demand (Source: ODPM); property transactions (Source: HM Land Registry and Inland Revenue); supply minus vacant housing (Source: ODPM) and average number of views per week (Source: Hometrack);
Neighbourhood characteristics: Percentage of unfit houses (Source: ODPM); crime rates (Source: ODPM); crime detection rates (Source: Home Office); percentage of university acceptances to applications (Source: Universities and Colleges Admissions Service (UCAS)); percentage of population of 16–24 year olds attending university (Source: UCAS); best value performance indicators (Source: ODPM) and
Market conditions: Average weekly household income (Source: ONS); unemployment rate (Source: Labour Force Survey (LFS)) and proportion of population claiming income support (Source: ONS).
We used monthly data on prices, degree-of-overpricing and time on the market, averaged for each region, from a detailed level of geographical and temporal disaggregation to estimate the parameters of the model. Our structural model of housing markets in England and Wales is estimated using monthly data at the three-digit postcode level, augmented with other information at the level of the government office regions. Under the assumption of a spatial regime model (Anselin, 1988), we allow heterogeneity across the regions. In other words, the models are estimated separately for each region, based on three-digit postcode-level data within the region. The residuals (at the three-digit postcode level) from these ten regional models for demand are used to estimate the cross-regional spatial covariance matrix (of dimension 10 × 10) used in the second stage of the SURE estimation.
The estimated model is multi-regional and enables analysis of housing markets in single regions and in conurbations. The estimated structural equation for demand, where demand depends on sales price, local neighbourhood characteristics and market conditions, incorporates unrestricted forms of spatial diffusion. The estimated cross-region spatial covariance matrix is then used to interpret the nature of spatial diffusion of demand across the GORs. For prices, DOP and TOM, we assume a random coefficients model and report mean group estimates combining evidence across the regions (Pesaran and Smith, 1995).
5. Results
A set of demand equations were estimated using the number of views per week as the dependent variable [2], measures of realised value (price), neighbourhood characteristics (unfit houses, access to education and crime detection rates) and indicators of market conditions (claimant counts and household income). The equations were estimated using two-stage least squares, where a proxy realised value was obtained from predictions using a number of instrumental variables, including supply, lagged endogenous variables, neighbourhood characteristics and market conditions.
Separate demand equations were estimated for each region and for England and Wales together. This permits study of unrestricted heterogeneity in the demand relationship across the regions, which is reasonable in the present context. It is well-known that, because correlations are low, instrumental variables methods can lead to poor results in cross-sectional analysis; see Bound et al. (1995) for further information. We consider the F-statistics of the first stage regressions for each of the endogenous variables in our model, and verify that the instruments in our estimated model are well-specified.
The estimates of the structural equation (Equation (7)), presented in Table 1, show substantial heterogeneity across the ten GORs in England and Wales. The effect of price changes on demand is, as expected, negative for all the regions. However, the coefficient shows substantial slope heterogeneity across the regions; in fact, estimated price elasticities are very small and not statistically significant at the 5% level for Wales and for Yorkshire and the Humber.
Neighbourhood characteristics have an important effect on demand. However, as with prices, the nature of this effect is heterogenous across the different regions. Demand in all regions is positively related to access to education; the coefficients are statistically significant at the 5% level in all regions except the South East (where the p-value is 0.096). This finding is in line with the conclusions of other studies concerning the effect of access to education on house prices; see Gibbons and Machin (2003), among others. The share of unfit houses is negatively related to demand in all regions except Wales, though the coefficients are not statistically significant for London, the East Midlands and the East of England. Crime detection has a positive effect on demand for housing in Yorkshire and the Humber.
The impact of neighbourhood characteristics on demand across the different GORs, as well as heterogeneity in these relationships, have important implications for housing policy. Access to education affects housing demand significantly across all the regions of England and Wales, while crime detection has an important effect in Yorkshire and the Humber. The quality of housing stock, measured by the proportion of unfit houses, has significant negative effects on housing demand in the regions South East, South West, North West, Yorkshire and the Humber and the North East.
As in the case of price changes and neighbourhood characteristics, market conditions also affect demand for housing; the strength and nature of the effect vary across the regions. Demand is negatively related to claimant counts in all the regions and is positively related to income in Yorkshire and the Humber. However, the effect of market conditions on demand is not statistically significant, at the 5% level, in the South East, East Midlands, North West and Yorkshire and the Humber.
In Table 1, we also report, as a benchmark, the results for England and Wales as a whole. As expected, because of substantial heterogeneity across the regions, these results are only indicative (Pesaran and Smith, 1995). Nevertheless, the results represent reasonably well the direction and strength of the underlying regression relationships. We also estimated the structural relationship for demand allowing for region-specific fixed effects; the results were very similar.
Like the structural equation for demand, we also estimated equations for price (Equation (6)), degree-of-overpricing (Equation (8)) and time on the market (Equation (9)), both for each individual region and for England and Wales as a whole. There is substantial heterogeneity across the regions, both in the specification and in the strength of the relationships; this implies that the estimated coefficients are only indicative.
Since our main focus here is on the demand relationship, we do not present these heterogenous model estimates here. Instead, we aggregate the regional estimates and present only the mean group estimates (Pesaran and Smith, 1995) for the structural equations averaged across regions in England and Wales (Table 2). These estimates represent the direction and strength of the regression relationships for the different regions.
The rental adjustment model for prices is well-specified, with house prices strongly and positively related to lagged prices and strongly and negatively related to lagged vacancy rates. As indicated by our structural model, the degree-of-overpricing is positively related to prices and demand; however, neither of these effects is statistically significant at the 5% level. Degree-of-overpricing is strongly and positively related to income and strongly and negatively related to crime rates; see also Gibbons (2004).
Consistent with the structural model, time on the market is strongly and positively related to degree-of-overpricing and is strongly and negatively related to growth in demand. Since supply is highly inelastic, growth in supply has positive effect but is not statistically significant. Changes in market conditions, as measured by an increase in claimant counts, have a negative effect; this reflects a stronger effect on time on the market from the demand side, where higher-income households tend to wait longer for a good match before buying a house.
As a first approach towards identification of the pattern of spatial autocorrelation across the regions, we estimate the structural equation for demand in a seemingly unrelated regression (SURE) framework (Zellner, 1962). In this approach, the spatial covariance matrix is estimated non-parametrically, that is, without specifying an explicit spatial process or functional form for distance decay (Fiebig, 1999; Anselin, 1999). Separate equations are estimated for each region and we allow the unexplained variation in demand to be contemporaneously correlated across the regions. This approach is consistent with the spatial regime model (Anselin, 1988) in that it allows heterogeneity in the demand relationship across the ten GORs in England and Wales. Further, in admitting correlated errors across the regions, the approach allows for completely unrestricted spatial autocorrelation. In other words, this assumes a very general treatment of a spatial error model, which is aligned with the spatial lag model (Anselin, 1988).
Table 3A presents the estimated spatial covariance matrix of the residuals across the ten regions. The spatial correlation matrix derived from this covariance matrix (Table 3B) shows some interesting spatial characteristics. While formal tests to negate strong spatial dependence along the lines of Pesaran (2015) are difficult because of the small spatial dimension, no dominant units are apparent. The results in Table 3B, in combination with those in Table 1, have interesting implications for region-specific housing policy.
The patterns of spatial correlation across the ten GORs indicate that spatial patterns in demand are, in some cases, explained by contiguity and geographical distance. These include: South East and the East of England; Yorkshire and the Humber and North East and East Midlands and East (the East of England).
However, there are possible alternative explanations for some spatial autocorrelations. The high correlation between Wales, the North East and Yorkshire and the Humber highlights the peripheral component of a core-periphery structure. One possible interpretation is that an external shock affects the periphery as a whole differently, and in some senses uniformly, compared to other regions.
It is interesting to note that the spatial errors for Greater London are not strongly correlated with the adjacent regions, South East and East. These two regions can therefore be regarded as substitutes in the choice of housing location; see also Bhattacharjee et al. (2022). This suggests that the regional markets are segmented in social terms, implying that while London is attractive for certain social or ethnic groups, these groups are less attracted by the housing markets in the East and South East. This view is also supported by the high spatial correlations between Greater London and the two regions of the West Midlands and East Midlands. Meen and Meen (2003) point to the importance of social interactions and segregation in understanding housing markets.
Thus, the pattern of spatial correlations provides interesting insights into the drivers of spatial diffusion in demand. While our analysis in this paper is indicative, the nature of spatial diffusion of demand requires more careful and detailed consideration. Explicit estimates of the spatial weights matrix offer similar interpretations (Bhattacharjee and Jensen-Butler, 2013). Understanding the nature of spatial diffusion is important for the design and conduct of region-specific housing policy as well as for understanding features of the UK housing markets, including ripple effects (Meen, 1996; Cook and Holly, 2000; Bhattacharjee et al., 2022). This leaves substantial scope for future research.
6. Conclusion
In this paper, we propose an economic model of regional housing markets in England and Wales, incorporating both the macroeconomic relationships between prices, demand and supply and a microeconomic model of search, matching and price formation. We estimate this micro-founded model of regional housing markets in England and Wales, incorporating heterogeneity across the regions and unrestricted patterns of spatial interactions. Notwithstanding substantial heterogeneity in the structure of housing markets across the different regions, the proposed economic model describes well the structure of housing markets in each of the regions. Further, we find significant spatial relationships in demand between GORs in England and Wales, many of which are readily interpreted, though a simple understanding in terms of contiguity and distance is clearly inadequate.
By incorporating heterogeneity at different levels, the approach potentially enables improved prediction of demand and prices in regional housing markets. Further, the approach also permits evaluation of the effects of spatially asymmetric shocks on the housing markets in all regions. The methodology allows heterogeneity in the specification of spatial diffusion in different regions and identifies region-specific drivers in the housing market. Hence, the methodology is useful both for explaining how regional housing markets function and in the evaluation of region-specific housing policy.
The work in this paper suggests several extensions and paths of model development. The estimated spatial autocorrelations across the regions indicate several distinct channels of spatial diffusion of demand. However, further work is necessary to identify the spatial processes through which housing demand in any one region is transformed by demand from other regions. A nuanced combination of how diffusion in the different regions is driven by different factors, including contiguity, distance, peripherality, position in the urban hierarchy as well as social and ethnic composition, requires further research.
Finally, in this work, we took housing supply as exogenous because it is largely driven by planning and other policy constraints. Housing supply in the UK is inadequate, particularly for some social and ethnic groups, and the gap between demand and supply varies substantially across the regions. Further research is needed to understand regional housing supply and housebuilding, its determinants and implications for housing and regional policy.
Figures
2SLS estimates, structural equation for demand
Regressors | Coeff | Std.Err | Coeff | Std.Err | Coeff | Std.Err |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
London | South East | South West | ||||
−2.266⋆⋆⋆ | 0.651 | −8.965⋆⋆⋆ | 2.304 | −4.360⋆⋆⋆ | 1.206 | |
ΔX1t | −1.871 | 1.265 | −10.439⋆⋆⋆ | 3.517 | ||
ΔX1,t−1 | −8.702⋆⋆⋆ | 2.237 | ||||
ΔX2t | 6.946⋆ | 4.173 | ||||
ΔX2,t−1 | 34.853⋆⋆⋆ | 9.640 | 83.215⋆⋆⋆ | 21.389 | ||
ΔY1t | −0.082 | 0.117 | −0.579⋆⋆⋆ | 0.222 | ||
ΔY1,t−1 | −0.690⋆⋆⋆ | 0.198 | ||||
Intercept | −0.002 | 0.029 | −0.061⋆⋆⋆ | 0.018 | −0.153⋆⋆⋆ | 0.046 |
East of England | East Midlands | West Midlands | ||||
−6.941⋆⋆⋆ | 1.866 | −4.863⋆⋆⋆ | 1.803 | −18.238⋆⋆ | 9.223 | |
ΔX1t | −7.934 | 6.232 | ||||
ΔX1,t−1 | −0.212 | 2.346 | ||||
ΔX2t | 12.032⋆⋆ | 5.476 | 52.665⋆⋆⋆ | 14.161 | ||
ΔX2,t−1 | 18.356⋆⋆⋆ | 6.378 | ||||
ΔY1,t−1 | −0.990⋆⋆⋆ | 0.301 | −0.044 | 0.133 | −1.092⋆⋆⋆ | 0.353 |
Intercept | 0.083⋆ | 0.048 | 0.028 | 0.022 | 0.237⋆ | 0.132 |
North West | Yorks. and Humber | North East | ||||
−15.903⋆⋆⋆ | 3.921 | −1.192 | 0.781 | −12.568⋆⋆⋆ | 3.161 | |
ΔX1t | −2.361⋆⋆⋆ | 0.678 | −7.563⋆⋆⋆ | 2.852 | −4.561⋆⋆⋆ | 1.262 |
ΔX2t | 99.869⋆⋆⋆ | 25.319 | 89.555⋆⋆⋆ | 23.018 | 73.461⋆⋆⋆ | 23.772 |
ΔX3t | 0.192⋆⋆ | 0.076 | ||||
ΔY1t | −0.034 | 0.118 | ||||
ΔY1,t−1 | −2.066⋆⋆⋆ | 0.556 | ||||
ΔY2t | 0.038 | 0.842 | ||||
Intercept | 0.052⋆⋆⋆ | 0.016 | 0.080⋆⋆ | 0.036 | 0.218⋆⋆⋆ | 0.059 |
Wales | All regions | |||||
−0.532 | 1.172 | −52.995⋆⋆⋆ | 12.426 | |||
ΔX1t | −0.370⋆⋆⋆ | 0.106 | ||||
ΔX2t | 12.696⋆⋆⋆ | 3.414 | ||||
ΔX2,t−1 | 38.998⋆⋆⋆ | 13.141 | ||||
ΔY1t | −0.949⋆⋆⋆ | 0.273 | ||||
ΔY1,t−1 | −0.336⋆⋆⋆ | 0.097 | ||||
Intercept | −0.062⋆⋆ | 0.028 | 0.831⋆⋆⋆ | 0.214 |
Note(s): Dependent variable: Δ ln Dt. Regressors –
Source(s): Authors’ own work
2SLS estimates, structural equations for prices, degree-of-overpricing and time on the market
Regressors | Coeff | Std.Err | Coeff | Std.Err | Coeff | Std.Err |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Prices | Degree-of-overpricing | Time on the market | ||||
0.041 | 0.065 | |||||
0.0021⋆ | 0.0011 | −2.129⋆⋆⋆ | 0.589 | |||
66.109⋆⋆⋆ | 16.992 | |||||
Δ ln St | 0.274 | 0.748 | ||||
Δ ln Vt−1 | 0.073⋆⋆⋆ | 0.020 | ||||
−0.0034⋆⋆⋆ | 0.0010 | |||||
ΔX4t | −0.0033⋆⋆⋆ | 0.0012 | ||||
ΔY1,t−1 | −0.328⋆⋆⋆ | 0.131 | ||||
Δ ln Y2t | 0.053⋆⋆⋆ | 0.015 | ||||
Intercept | 0.015⋆⋆⋆ | 0.004 | −0.0004 | 0.0018 | −0.016⋆⋆ | 0.008 |
Note(s): Dependent variables: Δ ln Vt, Δ ln DOPt, and ΔTOMt, respectively. Regressors –
Source(s): Authors’ own work
Spatial error covariances and correlations
Regions | E | EM | L | NE | NW | SE | SW | W | WM | YH |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
A. Errors, Spatial covariance matrix | ||||||||||
E | 0.014 | |||||||||
EM | 0.013 | 0.023 | ||||||||
L | 0.008 | 0.011 | 0.011 | |||||||
NE | 0.021 | 0.034 | 0.018 | 0.094 | ||||||
NW | 0.003 | 0.006 | 0.003 | 0.006 | 0.020 | |||||
SE | 0.010 | 0.010 | 0.007 | 0.018 | 0.001 | 0.010 | ||||
SW | 0.003 | 0.002 | 0.003 | −0.002 | 0.009 | 0.002 | 0.010 | |||
W | 0.023 | 0.036 | 0.019 | 0.100 | −0.009 | 0.022 | −0.013 | 0.152 | ||
WM | 0.006 | 0.010 | 0.008 | 0.016 | 0.005 | 0.006 | 0.004 | 0.133 | 0.011 | |
YH | 0.028 | 0.041 | 0.024 | 0.100 | −0.003 | 0.024 | −0.006 | 0.131 | 0.018 | 0.142 |
B. Errors, Spatial correlation matrix | ||||||||||
E | 1 | |||||||||
EM | 0.736 | 1 | ||||||||
L | 0.647 | 0.702 | 1 | |||||||
NE | 0.577 | 0.736 | 0.560 | 1 | ||||||
NW | 0.185 | 0.280 | 0.221 | 0.141 | 1 | |||||
SE | 0.832 | 0.692 | 0.680 | 0.607 | 0.100 | 1 | ||||
SW | 0.232 | 0.146 | 0.272 | −0.074 | 0.612 | 0.173 | 1 | |||
W | 0.493 | 0.598 | 0.474 | 0.834 | −0.171 | 0.579 | −0.331 | 1 | ||
WM | 0.473 | 0.631 | 0.724 | 0.509 | 0.358 | 0.552 | 0.359 | 0.329 | 1 | |
YH | 0.622 | 0.709 | 0.607 | 0.869 | −0.050 | 0.633 | −0.160 | 0.892 | 0.446 | 1 |
Note(s): Region abbreviations. E: East of England; EM: East Midlands; L: Greater London; NE: North East; NW: NorthWest; SE: South East; SW: SouthWest; W: Wales; WM: West Midlands and YH: Yorkshire and the Humber
Source(s): Authors’ own work
Notes
Also denoted NUTS1 or ITL1 regions.
We also experimented with several other measures of demand, and findings are qualitatively similar.
References
Anglin, P.M., Rutherford, R. and Springer, T.M. (2003), “The trade-off between selling price of residential properties and time-on-the-market: the impact of price setting”, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, Vol. 26 No. 1, pp. 95-111, doi: 10.1023/a:1021526332732.
Anselin, L. (1988), Spatial Econometrics: Methods and Models, Kluwer Academic, Dordrecht, The Netherlands.
Anselin, L. (1999), “Spatial econometrics”, in Baltagi, B.H. (Ed.), A Companion to Theoretical Econometrics, Basil Blackwell, Oxford, pp. 310-330.
Anselin, L. (2002), “Under the hood: issues in the specification and interpretation of spatial regression models”, Agricultural Economics, Vol. 27 No. 3, pp. 247-267, doi: 10.1111/j.1574-0862.2002.tb00120.x.
Anselin, L. and Lozano-Gracia, N. (2009), “Spatial hedonic models”, in Mills, T.C. and Patterson, K. (Eds), Palgrave Handbook of Econometrics, Volume 2: Applied Econometrics, Palgrave Macmillan, London, UK, pp. 1213-1250, Chapter 26.
Anselin, L., Lozano-Gracia, N., Deichmann, U. and Lall, S. (2010), “Valuing access to water – a spatial hedonic approach, with an application to Bangalore, India”, Spatial Economic Analysis, Vol. 5 No. 2, pp. 161-179, doi: 10.1080/17421771003730703.
Arnold, M.A. (1999), “Search, bargaining and optimal asking prices”, Real Estate Economics, Vol. 27 No. 3, pp. 453-482, doi: 10.1111/1540-6229.00780.
Ashworth, J. and Parker, S. (1997), “Modelling regional house prices in the UK”, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 44 No. 3, pp. 225-246, doi: 10.1111/1467-9485.00055.
Baltagi, B., Song, S.H. and Koh, W. (2003), “Testing panel data regression models with spatial error correlation”, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 117 No. 1, pp. 123-150, doi: 10.1016/s0304-4076(03)00120-9.
Barker, K. (2003), Review of Housing Supply, Interim Report, HM Treasury, London.
Barker, K. (2004), Review of Housing Supply, Final Report, HM Treasury, London.
Bhattacharjee, A. and Jensen-Butler, C. (2013), “Estimation of the spatial weights matrix under structural constraints”, Regional Science and Urban Economics, Vol. 43 No. 4, pp. 617-634, doi: 10.1016/j.regsciurbeco.2013.03.005.
Bhattacharjee, A., Castro, E., Maiti, T. and Marques, J. (2016), “Endogenous spatial regression and delineation of submarkets: a new framework with application to housing markets”, Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol. 31 No. 1, pp. 32-57, doi: 10.1002/jae.2478.
Bhattacharjee, A., Cai, L. and Maiti, T. (2017), “Functional regression over irregular domains: variation in the shadow price of living space”, Spatial Economic Analysis, Vol. 12 Nos 2-3, pp. 182-201, doi: 10.1080/17421772.2017.1286374.
Bhattacharjee, A., Ditzen, J. and Holly, S. (2022), “Spatial and spatio-temporal error correction, networks and common correlated effects”, in Chudik, A., Hsiao, C. and Timmermann, A. (Eds), Essays in Honor of M. Hashem Pesaran: Panel Modeling, Micro Applications, and Econometric Methodology’, Advances in Econometrics, Vol. 43B, Emerald Publishing, Leeds, pp. 37-60, Chapter 2.
Bhattacharjee, A., Castro, E. and Marques, J.L. (2024), “Modelling spatial urban housing markets”, in Gibb, K., Leishman, C., Marsh, A., Meen, G., ViforJ, R.O. and Watkins, C. (Eds), The‘Routledge Handbook of Housing Economics’, Routledge, pp. 27-42, Chapter 3.
Bound, J., Jaeger, D. and Baker, R. (1995), “Problems with instrumental variables estimation when the correlation between instruments and the endogenous explanatory variable is weak”, Journal of American Statistical Association, Vol. 90 No. 430, pp. 443-450, doi: 10.1080/01621459.1995.10476536.
Cai, L., Bhattacharjee, A., Calantone, R. and Maiti, T. (2019), “Variable selection with spatially autoregressive errors: a generalized moments LASSO estimator”, Sankhyā B, Vol. 81 No. 1, pp. 146-200, doi: 10.1007/s13571-018-0176-z.
Cameron, G. and Muellbauer, J. (1998), “The housing market and regional commuting and migration choices”, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 45 No. 4, pp. 420-446, doi: 10.1111/1467-9485.00106.
Cheshire, P. and Sheppard, S. (2004), “Capitalising the value of free schools: the impact of supply constraints and uncertainty”, The Economic Journal, Vol. 114 No. 499, pp. F397-F424, doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0297.2004.00252.x.
Cook, S. (2003), “The convergence of regional house prices in the UK”, Urban Studies, Vol. 40 No. 11, pp. 2285-2294, doi: 10.1080/0042098032000123295.
Cook, S. and Holly, S. (2000), “Statistical properties of UK house prices: an analysis of disaggregated vintages”, Urban Studies, Vol. 37 No. 11, pp. 2045-2055, doi: 10.1080/713707230.
Elhorst, J.P. (2003), “Specification and estimation of spatial panel data models”, International Regional Science Review, Vol. 26 No. 3, pp. 244-268, doi: 10.1177/0160017603253791.
Favilukis, J., Ludvigson, S.C. and Van Nieuwerburgh, S. (2017), “The macroeconomic effects of housing wealth, housing finance, and limited risk sharing in general equilibrium”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 125 No. 1, pp. 140-223, doi: 10.1086/689606.
Fiebig, D.G. (1999), “Seemingly unrelated regression”, in Baltagi, B.H. (Ed.), A Companion to Theoretical Econometrics, Basil Blackwell, Oxford, pp. 101-121.
Fuerst, F. (2004), “Forecasting the Manhattan office market with a simultaneous equation model”, Working Paper, Center for Urban Research, City University of New York.
Giacomini, R. and Granger, C.W.J. (2004), “Aggregation of space-time processes”, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 118 Nos 1-2, pp. 7-26, doi: 10.1016/s0304-4076(03)00132-5.
Gibbons, S. (2004), “The costs of urban property crime”, The Economic Journal, Vol. 114 No. 499, pp. F441-F463, doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0297.2004.00254.x.
Gibbons, S. and Machin, S. (2003), “Valuing English primary schools”, Journal of Urban Economics, Vol. 53 No. 2, pp. 197-219, doi: 10.1016/s0094-1190(02)00516-8.
Gibbons, S. and Machin, S. (2005), “Valuing rail access using transport innovations”, Journal of Urban Economics, Vol. 57 No. 1, pp. 148-169, doi: 10.1016/j.jue.2004.10.002.
Hendershott, P. (1996), “Rental adjustment and valuation in overbuilt markets: evidence from the Sydney office market”, Journal of Urban Economics, Vol. 39 No. 1, pp. 51-67, doi: 10.1006/juec.1996.0003.
Hendershott, P., MacGregor, B. and White, M. (2002), “Explaining real commercial rents using an error correction model with panel data”, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, Vol. 24, pp. 59-87, doi: 10.1007/978-1-4757-5988-4_4.
Holmans, A.E. (1990), “House prices: changes through time at national and sub-national level”, Government Economic Service Working Paper No. 110, HMSO, London.
Hsieh, T.-C. and Moretti, E. (2019), “Housing constraints and spatial misallocation”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, Vol. 11 No. 2, pp. 1-39, doi: 10.1257/mac.20170388.
Kelejian, H.H. and Prucha, I.R. (2004), “Estimation of simultaneous systems of spatially interrelated cross sectional equations”, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 118 Nos 1-2, pp. 27-50, doi: 10.1016/s0304-4076(03)00133-7.
Krainer, J. (2001), “A theory of liquidity in residential real estate markets”, Journal of Urban Economics, Vol. 49 No. 1, pp. 32-53, doi: 10.1006/juec.2000.2180.
Maclennan, D. and Long, J. (2024), “A missing perspective in housing economics: productivity?”, in Gibb, K., Leishman, C., Marsh, A., Meen, G., ViforJ, R.O. and Watkins, C. (Eds), The‘Routledge Handbook of Housing Economics’, Routledge, pp. 149-162, Chapter 12.
Meen, G. (1996), “Ten propositions in UK housing macroeconomics: an overview of the 1980s and early 1990s”, Urban Studies, Vol. 33 No. 3, pp. 425-444, doi: 10.1080/00420989650011843.
Meen, G. (1999), “Regional house prices and the ripple effect: a new interpretation”, Housing Studies, Vol. 14 No. 6, pp. 733-753, doi: 10.1080/02673039982524.
Meen, G. (2001), Modelling Spatial Housing Markets: Theory, Analysis and Policy, Kluwer Academic, Boston.
Meen, G. (2003), “Regional housing supply elasticities in England”, Report prepared for the barker review of housing supply, Centre for Spatial and Real Estate Economics, University of Reading, October 2003.
Meen, G. (2008), “Ten new propositions in UK housing macroeconomics: an overview of the first years of the century”, Urban Studies, Vol. 45 No. 13, pp. 2759-2781, doi: 10.1177/0042098008098205.
Meen, D. and Meen, G. (2003), “Social behaviour as a basis for modelling the urban housing market: a review”, Urban Studies, Vol. 40 Nos 5-6, pp. 917-935, doi: 10.1080/0042098032000074245.
Muellbauer, J. (2003), “Housing, credit and the Euro: the Policy response”, Report prepared for the Barker Review of Housing Supply.
Muellbauer, J. and Murphy, A. (1997), “Booms and busts in the UK housing market”, The Economic Journal, Vol. 107 No. 445, pp. 1720-1746, doi: 10.1111/1468-0297.00251.
Pesaran, M.H. (2015), “Testing weak cross-sectional dependence in large panels”, Econometric Reviews, Vol. 34 Nos 6-10, pp. 1089-1117, doi: 10.1080/07474938.2014.956623.
Pesaran, M.H. and Smith, R.P. (1995), “Estimating long-run relationships from dynamic heterogeneous panels”, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 68 No. 1, pp. 79-113, doi: 10.1016/0304-4076(94)01644-f.
Pesaran, M.H. and Tosetti, E. (2011), “Large panels with common factors and spatial correlation”, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 161 No. 2, pp. 182-202, doi: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2010.12.003.
Rosenthal, S. (1999), “Residential buildings and the cost of construction: new evidence from the housing market”, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 81 No. 2, pp. 288-302, doi: 10.1162/003465399558085.
Wheaton, W.C. (1990), “Vacancy, search and prices in a housing market matching model”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98 No. 6, pp. 1270-1292, doi: 10.1086/261734.
Wheaton, W.C. and Torto, R.G. (1993), “Office rent indices and their behavior over time”, Journal of Urban Economics, Vol. 35 No. 2, pp. 112-139, doi: 10.1006/juec.1994.1008.
Wheaton, W.C., Torto, R.G. and Evans, P. (1997), “The cyclic behavior of the Greater London office market”, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, Vol. 15 No. 1, pp. 77-92, doi: 10.1023/a:1007701422238.
White, M. (2024), “Housing market liquidity”, in Gibb, K., Leishman, C., Marsh, A., Meen, G., ViforJ, R.O. and Watkins, C. (Eds), The‘Routledge Handbook of Housing Economics’, Routledge, pp. 133-148, Chapter 11.
Yavas, A. (1992), “A simple search and bargaining model of real estate markets”, Journal of American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association, Vol. 20 No. 4, pp. 533-548, doi: 10.1111/1540-6229.00595.
Zellner, A. (1962), “An efficient method of estimating seemingly unrelated regressions and tests for aggregation bias”, Journal of the American Statistical Association, Vol. 57 No. 298, pp. 348-368, doi: 10.2307/2281644.
Acknowledgements
This paper is dedicated to the fond and loving memory of the late Chris Jensen-Butler. We thank Donald Haurin, Duncan Maclennan, Geoff Meen and Adrian Pabst for valuable comments on the paper. We also thank Hometrack and particularly David Catt for access to data used in this paper. The usual disclaimer applies.